Posted on 07/27/2005 6:21:50 AM PDT by A. Pole
The June payroll jobs report did not receive much attention due to the July 4 holiday, but the depressing 21st century job performance of the U.S. economy continues unabated.
Only 144,000 private sector jobs were created, each one of which was in domestic services.
Fifty-six thousand jobs were created in professional and business services, about half of which are in administrative and waste services.
Thirty-eight thousand jobs were created in education and health services, almost all of which are in health care and social assistance.
Nineteen thousand jobs were created in leisure and hospitality, almost all of which are waitresses and bartenders.
Membership associations and organizations created 10,000 jobs, and repair and maintenance created 4,000 jobs.
Financial activities created 16,000 jobs.
This most certainly is not the labor market profile of a First World country, much less a superpower.
Where are the jobs for this years crop of engineering and science graduates?
U.S. manufacturing lost another 24,000 jobs in June. A country that doesnt manufacture doesnt need many engineers. And the few engineering jobs available go to foreigners.
Readers have sent me employment listings from U.S. software development firms. The listings are discriminatory against American citizens. One ad from a company in New Jersey that is a developer for many companies, including Oracle, specifies that the applicant must have a TN visa.
A TN or Trade NAFTA visa is what is given to Mexicans and Canadians who are willing to work in the United States at below prevailing wages.
Another ad from a software consulting company based in Omaha, Neb., specifies it wants software engineers who are H-1B transferees. What this means is that the firm is advertising for foreigners already in the United States who have H-1B work visas.
The reason the U.S. firms specify that they have employment opportunities only for foreigners who hold work visas is because the foreigners will work for less than the prevailing U.S. salary.
Gentle reader, when you read allegations that there is a shortage of engineers in America, necessitating the importation of foreigners to do the work, you are reading a bald-faced lie. If there were a shortage of American engineers, employers would not word their job listings to read that no American need apply and that they are offering jobs only to foreigners holding work visas.
What kind of country gives preference to foreigners over its own engineering graduates?
What kind of country destroys the job market for its own citizens?
How much longer will parents shell out $100,000 for a college education for a son or daughter who ends up employed as a bartender, waitress or temp?
Is this an autobiographical boast? You really think you are better educated than Alexander Hamilton or James Madison?
Well, whatever, let's turn it around on you. When was the last time you read a paper by a Cambridge economist or attended his/her seminar?
Perhaps you will find this edifying seeing what the Cambridge marxists there are teaching their nation's buddies back in Bejing:
Kicking Away the Ladder:
How the Economic and Intellectual Histories of Capitalism Have Been Re-Written to Justify Neo-Liberal Capitalism
By Dr. Ha-Joon Chang (Prof. Econ., Cambridge University, UK) (2002)
There is currently great pressure on developing countries to adopt a set of good policies and good institutions such as liberalisation of trade and investment and strong patent law to foster their economic development. When some developing countries show reluctance in adopting them, the proponents of this recipe often find it difficult to understand these countries stupidity in not accepting such a tried and tested recipe for development. After all, they argue, these are the policies and the institutions that the developed countries had used in the past in order to become rich. Their belief in their own recommendation is so absolute that in their view it has to be imposed on the developing countries through strong bilateral and multilateral external pressures, even when these countries dont want them.
Naturally, there have been heated debates on whether these recommended policies and institutions are appropriate for developing countries. However, curiously, even many of those who are sceptical of the applicability of these policies and institutions to the developing countries take it for granted that these were the policies and the institutions that were used by the developed countries when they themselves were developing countries.
Contrary to the conventional wisdom, the historical fact is that the rich countries did not develop on the basis of the policies and the institutions that they now recommend to, and often force upon, the developing countries. Unfortunately, this fact is little known these days because the official historians of capitalism have been very successful in re-writing its history.
Almost all of todays rich countries used tariff protection and subsidies to develop their industries. Interestingly, Britain and the USA, the two countries that are supposed to have reached the summit of the world economy through their free-market, free-trade policy, are actually the ones that had most aggressively used protection and subsidies.
Contrary to the popular myth, Britain had been an aggressive user, and in certain areas a pioneer, of activist policies intended to promote its industries. Such policies, although limited in scope, date back from the 14th century (Edward III) and the 15th century (Henry VII) in relation to woollen manufacturing, the leading industry of the time. England then was an exporter of raw wool to the Low Countries, and Henry VII for example tried to change this by taxing raw wool exports and poaching skilled workers from the Low Countries.
Particularly between the trade policy reform of its first Prime Minister Robert Walpole in 1721 and its adoption of free trade around 1860, Britain used very dirigiste trade and industrial policies, involving measures very similar to what countries like Japan and Korea later used in order to develop their industries. During this period, it protected its industries a lot more heavily than did France, the supposed dirigiste counterpoint to its free-trade, free-market system. Given this history, argued Friedrich List, the leading German economist of the mid-19th century, Britain preaching free trade to less advanced countries like Germany and the USA was like someone trying to kick away the ladder with which he had climbed to the top.
List was not alone in seeing the matter in this light. Many American thinkers shared this view. Indeed, it was American thinkers like Alexander Hamilton, the first Treasury Secretary of the USA, and the (now-forgotten) economist Daniel Raymond, who first systematically developed the infant industry argument. Indeed, List, who is commonly known as the father of the infant industry argument, in fact started out as a free-trader (he was an ardent supporter of German customs union Zollverein) and learnt about this argument during his exile in the USA during the 1820s
Little known today, the intellectual interaction between the USA and Germany during the 19th century did not end there. The German Historical School represented by people like Wilhelm Roscher, Bruno Hildebrand, Karl Knies, Gustav Schmoller, and Werner Sombart attracted a lot of American economists in the late 19th century. The patron saint of American Neoclassical economics, John Bates Clark, in whose name the most prestigious award for young (under 40) American economists is given today, went to Germany in 1873 and studied the German Historical School under Roscher and Knies, although he gradually drifted away from it. Richard Ely, one of the leading American economists of the time, also studied under Knies and influenced the American Institutionalist School through his disciple, John Commons. Ely was one of the founding fathers of the American Economic Association; to this day, the biggest public lecture at the Associations annual meeting is given in Elys name, although few of the present AEA members would know who he was.
Between the Civil War and the Second World War, the USA was literally the most heavily protected economy in the world. In this context, it is important to note that the American Civil War was fought on the issue of tariff as much as, if not more, on the issue of slavery. Of the two major issues that divided the North and the South, the South had actually more to fear on the tariff front than on the slavery front. Abraham Lincoln was a well-known protectionist who cut his political teeth under the charismatic politician Henry Clay in the Whig Party, which advocated the American System based on infrastructural development and protectionism (thus named on recognition that free trade is for the British interest). One of Lincolns top economic advisors was the famous protectionist economist, Henry Carey, who once was described as the only American economist of importance by Marx and Engels in the early 1850s but has now been almost completely air-brushed out of the history of American economic thought. On the other hand, Lincoln thought that African Americans were racially inferior and that slave emancipation was an idealistic proposal with no prospect of immediate implementation he is said to have emancipated the slaves in 1862 as a strategic move to win the War rather than out of some moral conviction.
In protecting their industries, the Americans were going against the advice of such prominent economists as Adam Smith and Jean Baptiste Say, who saw the countrys future in agriculture. However, the Americans knew exactly what the game was. They knew that Britain reached the top through protection and subsidies and therefore that they needed to do the same if they were going to get anywhere. Criticising the British preaching of free trade to his country, Ulysses Grant, the Civil War hero and the US President between 1868-1876, retorted that within 200 years, when America has gotten out of protection all that it can offer, it too will adopt free trade. When his country later reached the top after the Second World War, it too started kicking away the ladder by preaching and forcing free trade to the less developed countries.
The UK and the USA may be the more dramatic examples, but almost all the rest of the developed world today used tariffs, subsidies and other means to promote their industries in the earlier stages of their development. Cases like Germany, Japan, and Korea are well known in this respect. But even Sweden, which later came to represent the small open economy to many economists had also strategically used tariffs, subsidies, cartels, and state support for R&D to develop key industries, especially textile, steel, and engineering.
There were some exceptions like the Netherlands and Switzerland that have maintained free trade since the late 18th century. However, these were countries that were already on the frontier of technological development by the 18th centuries and therefore did not need much protection. Also, it should be noted that the Netherlands deployed an impressive range of interventionist measures up till the 17th century in order to build up its maritime and commercial supremacy. Moreover, Switzerland did not have a patent law until 1907, flying directly against the emphasis that todays orthodoxy puts on the protection of intellectual property rights (see below). More interestingly, the Netherlands abolished its 1817 patent law in 1869 on the ground that patents are politically-created monopolies inconsistent with its free-market principles a position that seems to elude most of todays free-market economists and did not introduce another patent law until 1912.
The story is similar in relation to institutional development. In the earlier stages of their development, todays developed countries did not even have such basic institutions as professional civil service, central bank, and patent law. It was only after the Pendleton Act in 1883 that the US federal government started recruiting its employees through a competitive process. The central bank, an institution dear to the heart of todays free-market economists, did not exist in most of todays rich countries until the early 20th century not least because the free-market economists of the day condemned it as a mechanism for unjustly bailing out imprudent borrowers. The US central bank (the Federal Reserve Board) was set up only in 1913 and the Italian central bank did not even have a note issue monopoly until 1926. Many countries allowed patenting of foreign invention until the late 19th century. As I mentioned above, Switzerland and the Netherlands refused to introduce a patent law despite international pressure until 1907 and 1912 respectively, thus freely stole technologies from abroad. The examples can go on.
One important conclusion that emerges from the history of institutional development is that it took the developed countries a long time to develop institutions in their earlier days of development. Institutions typically took decades, and sometimes generations, to develop. Just to give one example, the need for central banking was perceived at least in some circles from at least the 17th century, but the first real central bank, the Bank of England, was instituted only in 1844, some two centuries later.
Another important point emerges is that the levels of institutional development in todays developed countries in the earlier period were much lower than those in todays developing countries. For example, measured by the (admittedly highly imperfect) income level, in 1820, the UK was at a somewhat higher level of development than that of India today, but it did not even have many of the most basic institutions that India has today. It did not have universal suffrage (it did not even have universal male suffrage), a central bank, income tax, generalised limited liability, a generalised bankruptcy law, a professional bureaucracy, meaningful securities regulations, and even minimal labour regulations (except for a couple of minimal and hardly-enforced regulations on child labour).
If the policies and institutions that the rich countries are recommending to the poor countries are not the ones that they themselves used when they were developing, what is going on? We can only conclude that the rich countries are trying to kick away the ladder that allowed them to climb where they are. It is no coincidence that economic development has become more difficult during the last two decades when the developed countries started turning on the pressure on the developing countries to adopt the so-called global standard policies and institutions.
During this period, the average annual per capita income growth rate for the developing countries has been halved from 3% in the previous two decades (1960-80) to 1.5%. In particular, Latin America virtually stopped growing, while Sub-Saharan Africa and most ex-Communist countries have experienced a fall in absolute income. Economic instability has increased markedly, as manifested in the dozens of financial crises we have witnessed over the last decade alone. Income inequality has been growing in many developing countries and poverty has increased, rather than decreased, in a significant number of them.
What can be done to change this?
First, the historical facts about the historical experiences of the developed countries should be more widely publicised. This is not just a matter of getting history right, but also of allowing the developing countries to make more informed choices.
Second, the conditions attached to bilateral and multilateral financial assistance to developing countries should be radically changed. It should be accepted that the orthodox recipe is not working, and also that there can be no best practice policies that everyone should use.
Third, the WTO rules should be re-written so that the developing countries can more actively use tariffs and subsidies for industrial development. They should also be allowed to have less stringent patent laws and other intellectual property rights laws.
Fourth, improvements in institutions should be encouraged, but this should not be equated with imposing a fixed set of (in practice, todays not even yesterdays Anglo-American) institutions on all countries. Special care has to be taken in order not to demand excessively rapid upgrading of institutions by the developing countries, especially given that they already have quite developed institutions when compared to todays developed countries at comparable stages of development, and given that establishing and running new institutions is costly.
By being allowed to adopt policies and institutions that are more suitable to their conditions, the developing countries will be able to develop faster. This will also benefit the developed countries in the long run, as it will increase their trade and investment opportunities. That the developed countries cannot see this is the tragedy of our time.
___________________
Ha-Joon Chang (hjc1001@econ.cam.ac.uk) teaches in the Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge. This article is based on his new book, Kicking Away the Ladder Development Strategy in Historical Perspective, which was published by Anthem Press, London, on 10 June 2002.
SUGGESTED CITATION:
Ha-Joon Chang, Kicking Away the Ladder, post-autistic economics review, issue no. 15, September 4, 2002, article 3. http://www.btinternet.com/~pae_news/review/issue15.htm
Ping.
I completely agree with everything you said. But, if I may ask, what is the relationship of all this with anything I said? Is this addressed to me by mistake?
For more info on the uproar, The Dead Pelican
"America did not become prosperous because of what Founding Fathers said about economics: it became prosperous because of what they did NOT say."
My intent was to show that America was likley prosperous before the founding fathers said--or did not say--anything.
Perhaps America's continued prosperity owed something to what the founders did or did not say--but that was likely not the origin of that prosperity.
(I suspect the origin of that prosperity had much to do with a continent brand-new to the uses of Western man,--
And hence brimming with aboundant natural resources, including high quality cheap land--
Plenty of the very best raw material of all kinds for a small population--
Whereas in Europe every square inch was owned and jealously guarded for generations,
With millions of Europeans having little hope of owning their own farms, slaving under laws slanted by the influential landowners to keep it that way, all killing innovation and industry.
Or whatever industry could be expected from land and resources depleted through generations of use.
Unlike Europe, land in America was so plentiful the rich did not need to conspire to keep it from the multitudes, anymore than they would have needed to conspire to keep the sky to themselves.
Truer words have not been written! :-)
That was my point exactly.
Since your brain seems to be functioning poorly, I'll spell it out for you.
You free trade type continually prattle about what the "experts" say. Well the economics experts were dead wrong during the 90's about what was best for Latin America and Russia.
Not at all; I am doing just fine, thank you.
I'll spell it out for you.
Thank you again. But before doing it for me, perhaps you should learn something yourself?
Well the economics experts were dead wrong during the 90's about what was best for Latin America and Russia.
Your brain is functioning well, you appear to think, and yet you are completely illogical: even if what you say were true and economists made a mistake, why does it mean that they make a mistake in another area. If you make a wrong turn on a highway, does that mean that nobody should ever listen to what you say?
Finally, where on eartch did you get that economists were wrong about Russia and Latin America? And, specifically, what is that "they" said?
Don't you know? Supply and demand. If the demand for talented investor falls or their supply increases, his salary will go down.
Now, when was the last time you asked: an NBA star --- whose main talent is pushin a round rabber thing through a hoop, 'mind you --- makes $30 million from being a "spokesperson" for MCI, what the heck is THAT about?
That "srar" spent a few days in total on shooting commercials. By comparison, that 28-year-old works 14-hour days and has no vacations. Somehow THAT bothers you.
Why?
Nah, they'll start with Bush, Republicans, free trade...
The money itself paid to the individual doesn't bother me. I'm a firm believer in the idea that a person is worth whatever he or she can negotiate. But sometimes the pay is out of proportion to the job.
Something tells me this is not EP's first incarnation on FR.
Do you mean he was forced to exit through the ZOT purge?
And the relevance of this is what exactly?
So, you have nothing to say in reply to WHAT I said and try to dig up some dirt on me? Is that not what you accuse DU and the Clintonites of doing? All the while feeling sooooo superior?
"Ha-Joon Chang, Kicking Away the Ladder, post-autistic economics review, issue no. 15, September 4, 2002, article 3."
Am I imagining things or is Exitpurge avoiding replying to you?
Not at all. I tried to have a dialog. The response is incoherent and irrelevant to anything I said. Paul seems to have problems with other posters as well (not you; you are more lucky, I gather).
Have a good day.
I am sorry if my post was unclear. I did not decry the lack of savings as much as lack of investment in ourselves: learning new computer skills, a technology adjacent to our own, a foreign language, etc. --- all this make one more competitive. We gave children terrific education up until 1950s-60s, when feel-good orientation replaced results-oriented approach. We even deal with illiteracy now. How do you think illiterate people can compete?
were a family to forgo consumption by sticking with their older TV in favor of savings what happens. The interest they earn, already low, is taxed at the highest rate they pay.
This is only a part of equation. The family that does not save still wants medical care. It demands it from the employer. The employer says "no" be not hiring them. What is the cost of that TV? Was it better to save to spend on that TV.
And that is what appears to happen now. People want to have their cake (big-screen TVs, big houses, etc) and eat it too (gimme health care, education for my kids). These demands make our, American labor more expensive, and the jobs go elsewhere.
Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.