Posted on 06/23/2005 12:58:30 PM PDT by truth49
Justice Thomas, dissenting.
Long ago, William Blackstone wrote that the law of the land postpone[s] even public necessity to the sacred and inviolable rights of private property. 1 Commentaries on the Laws of England 134135 (1765) (hereinafter Blackstone). The Framers embodied that principle in the Constitution, allowing the government to take property not for public necessity, but instead for public use. Amdt. 5. Defying this understanding, the Court replaces the Public Use Clause with a [P]ublic [P]urpose Clause, ante, at 910 (or perhaps the Diverse and Always Evolving Needs of Society Clause, ante, at 8 (capitalization added)), a restriction that is satisfied, the Court instructs, so long as the purpose is legitimate and the means not irrational, ante, at 17 (internal quotation marks omitted). This deferential shift in phraseology enables the Court to hold, against all common sense, that a costly urban-renewal project whose stated purpose is a vague promise of new jobs and increased tax revenue, but which is also suspiciously agreeable to the Pfizer Corporation, is for a public use.
I cannot agree. If such economic development takings are for a public use, any taking is, and the Court has erased the Public Use Clause from our Constitution, as Justice OConnor powerfully argues in dissent. Ante, at 12, 813. I do not believe that this Court can eliminate liberties expressly enumerated in the Constitution and therefore join her dissenting opinion. Regrettably, however, the Courts error runs deeper than this. Todays decision is simply the latest in a string of our cases construing the Public Use Clause to be a virtual nullity, without the slightest nod to its original meaning. In my view, the Public Use Clause, originally understood, is a meaningful limit on the governments eminent domain power. Our cases have strayed from the Clauses original meaning, and I would reconsider them.
I
The Fifth Amendment provides:
No person shall be held to answer for a capital, or otherwise infamous crime, unless on a presentment or indictment of a Grand Jury, except in cases arising in the land or naval forces, or in the Militia, when in actual service in time of War or public danger; nor shall any person be subject for the same offence to be twice put in jeopardy of life or limb, nor shall be compelled in any criminal case to be a witness against himself, nor be deprived of life, liberty, or property, without due process, of law; nor shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation. (Emphasis added.)
It is the last of these liberties, the Takings Clause, that is at issue in this case. In my view, it is imperative that the Court maintain absolute fidelity to the Clauses express limit on the power of the government over the individual, no less than with every other liberty expressly enumerated in the Fifth Amendment or the Bill of Rights more generally. Shepard v. United States, 544 U.S. ___, ___ (2005) (slip op., at 2) (Thomas, J., concurring in part and concurring in judgment) (internal quotation marks omitted).
Though one component of the protection provided by the Takings Clause is that the government can take private property only if it provides just compensation for the taking, the Takings Clause also prohibits the government from taking property except for public use. Were it otherwise, the Takings Clause would either be meaningless or empty. If the Public Use Clause served no function other than to state that the government may take property through its eminent domain powerfor public or private usesthen it would be surplusage. See ante, at 34 (OConnor, J., dissenting); see also Marbury v. Madison, 1 Cranch 137, 174 (1803) (It cannot be presumed that any clause in the constitution is intended to be without effect); Myers v. United States, 272 U.S. 52, 151 (1926). Alternatively, the Clause could distinguish those takings that require compensation from those that do not. That interpretation, however, would permit private property to be taken or appropriated for private use without any compensation whatever. Cole v. La Grange, 113 U.S. 1, 8 (1885) (interpreting same language in the Missouri Public Use Clause). In other words, the Clause would require the government to compensate for takings done for public use, leaving it free to take property for purely private uses without the payment of compensation. This would contradict a bedrock principle well established by the time of the founding: that all takings required the payment of compensation. 1 Blackstone 135; 2 J. Kent, Commentaries on American Law 275 (1827) (hereinafter Kent); J. Madison, for the National Property Gazette, (Mar. 27, 1792), in 14 Papers of James Madison 266, 267 (R. Rutland et al. eds. 1983) (arguing that no property shall be taken directly even for public use without indemnification to the owner).1 The Public Use Clause, like the Just Compensation Clause, is therefore an express limit on the governments power of eminent domain.
The most natural reading of the Clause is that it allows the government to take property only if the government owns, or the public has a legal right to use, the property, as opposed to taking it for any public purpose or necessity whatsoever. At the time of the founding, dictionaries primarily defined the noun use as [t]he act of employing any thing to any purpose. 2 S. Johnson, A Dictionary of the English Language 2194 (4th ed. 1773) (hereinafter Johnson). The term use, moreover, is from the Latin utor, which means to use, make use of, avail ones self of, employ, apply, enjoy, etc. J. Lewis, Law of Eminent Domain §165, p. 224, n. 4 (1888) (hereinafter Lewis). When the government takes property and gives it to a private individual, and the public has no right to use the property, it strains language to say that the public is employing the property, regardless of the incidental benefits that might accrue to the public from the private use. The term public use, then, means that either the government or its citizens as a whole must actually employ the taken property. See id., at 223 (reviewing founding-era dictionaries).
Granted, another sense of the word use was broader in meaning, extending to [c]onvenience or help, or [q]ualities that make a thing proper for any purpose. 2 Johnson 2194. Nevertheless, read in context, the term public use possesses the narrower meaning. Elsewhere, the Constitution twice employs the word use, both times in its narrower sense. Claeys, Public-Use Limitations and Natural Property Rights, 2004 Mich. St. L. Rev. 877, 897 (hereinafter Public Use Limitations). Article 1, §10 provides that the net Produce of all Duties and Imposts, laid by any State on Imports or Exports, shall be for the Use of the Treasury of the United States, meaning the Treasury itself will control the taxes, not use it to any beneficial end. And Article I, §8 grants Congress power [t]o raise and support Armies, but no Appropriation of Money to that Use shall be for a longer Term than two Years. Here again, use means employed to raise and support Armies, not anything directed to achieving any military end. The same word in the Public Use Clause should be interpreted to have the same meaning.
Tellingly, the phrase public use contrasts with the very different phrase general Welfare used elsewhere in the Constitution. See ibid. (Congress shall have Power To provide for the common Defence and general Welfare of the United States); preamble (Constitution established to promote the general Welfare). The Framers would have used some such broader term if they had meant the Public Use Clause to have a similarly sweeping scope. Other founding-era documents made the contrast between these two usages still more explicit. See Sales, Classical Republicanism and the Fifth Amendments Public Use Requirement, 49 Duke L. J. 339, 368 (2000) (hereinafter Sales) (noting contrast between, on the one hand, the term public use used by 6 of the first 13 States and, on the other, the terms public exigencies employed in the Massachusetts Bill of Rights and the Northwest Ordinance, and the term public necessity used in the Vermont Constitution of 1786). The Constitutions text, in short, suggests that the Takings Clause authorizes the taking of property only if the public has a right to employ it, not if the public realizes any conceivable benefit from the taking.
The Constitutions common-law background reinforces this understanding. The common law provided an express method of eliminating uses of land that adversely impacted the public welfare: nuisance law. Blackstone and Kent, for instance, both carefully distinguished the law of nuisance from the power of eminent domain. Compare 1 Blackstone 135 (noting governments power to take private property with compensation), with 3 id., at 216 (noting action to remedy public nuisances, which affect the public and are an annoyance to all the kings subjects); see also 2 Kent 274276 (distinguishing the two). Blackstone rejected the idea that private property could be taken solely for purposes of any public benefit. So great is the regard of the law for private property, he explained, that it will not authorize the least violation of it; no, not even for the general good of the whole community. 1 Blackstone 135. He continued: If a new road were to be made through the grounds of a private person, it might perhaps be extensively beneficial to the public; but the law permits no man, or set of men, to do this without the consent of the owner of the land. Ibid. Only by giving [the landowner] full indemnification could the government take property, and even then [t]he public [was] now considered as an individual, treating with an individual for an exchange. Ibid. When the public took property, in other words, it took it as an individual buying property from another typically would: for ones own use. The Public Use Clause, in short, embodied the Framers understanding that property is a natural, fundamental right, prohibiting the government from tak[ing] property from A. and giv[ing] it to B. Calder v. Bull, 3 Dall. 386, 388 (1798); see also Wilkinson v. Leland, 2 Pet. 627, 658 (1829); Vanhornes Lessee v. Dorrance, 2 Dall. 304, 311 (CC Pa. 1795).
The public purpose interpretation of the Public Use Clause also unnecessarily duplicates a similar inquiry required by the Necessary and Proper Clause. The Takings Clause is a prohibition, not a grant of power: The Constitution does not expressly grant the Federal Government the power to take property for any public purpose whatsoever. Instead, the Government may take property only when necessary and proper to the exercise of an expressly enumerated power. See Kohl v. United States, 91 U.S. 367, 371372 (1876) (noting Federal Governments power under the Necessary and Proper Clause to take property needed for forts, armories, and arsenals, for navy-yards and light-houses, for custom-houses, post-offices, and court-houses, and for other public uses). For a law to be within the Necessary and Proper Clause, as I have elsewhere explained, it must bear an obvious, simple, and direct relation to an exercise of Congress enumerated powers, Sabri v. United States, 541 U.S. 600, 613 (2004) (Thomas, J., concurring in judgment), and it must not subvert basic principles of constitutional design, Gonzales v. Raich, ante, at __ (Thomas, J., dissenting). In other words, a taking is permissible under the Necessary and Proper Clause only if it serves a valid public purpose. Interpreting the Public Use Clause likewise to limit the government to take property only for sufficiently public purposes replicates this inquiry. If this is all the Clause means, it is, once again, surplusage. See supra, at 3. The Clause is thus most naturally read to concern whether the property is used by the public or the government, not whether the purpose of the taking is legitimately public.
II
Early American eminent domain practice largely bears out this understanding of the Public Use Clause. This practice concerns state limits on eminent domain power, not the Fifth Amendment, since it was not until the late 19th century that the Federal Government began to use the power of eminent domain, and since the Takings Clause did not even arguably limit state power until after the passage of the Fourteenth Amendment. See Note, The Public Use Limitation on Eminent Domain: An Advance Requiem, 58 Yale L. J. 599, 599600, and nn. 34 (1949); Barron ex rel. Tiernan v. Mayor of Baltimore, 7 Pet. 243, 250251 (1833) (holding the Takings Clause inapplicable to the States of its own force). Nevertheless, several early state constitutions at the time of the founding likewise limited the power of eminent domain to public uses. See Sales 367369, and n. 137 (emphasis deleted). Their practices therefore shed light on the original meaning of the same words contained in the Public Use Clause.
States employed the eminent domain power to provide quintessentially public goods, such as public roads, toll roads, ferries, canals, railroads, and public parks. Lewis §§166, 168171, 175, at 227228, 234241, 243. Though use of the eminent domain power was sparse at the time of the founding, many States did have so-called Mill Acts, which authorized the owners of grist mills operated by water power to flood upstream lands with the payment of compensation to the upstream landowner. See, e.g., id., §178, at 245246; Head v. Amoskeag Mfg. Co., 113 U.S. 9, 1619, and n. (1885). Those early grist mills were regulated by law and compelled to serve the public for a stipulated toll and in regular order, and therefore were actually used by the public. Lewis §178, at 246, and n. 3; see also Head, supra, at 1819. They were common carriersquasi-public entities. These were public uses in the fullest sense of the word, because the public could legally use and benefit from them equally. See Public Use Limitations 903 (common-carrier status traditionally afforded to private beneficiaries of a state franchise or another form of state monopoly, or to companies that operated in conditions of natural monopoly).
To be sure, some early state legislatures tested the limits of their state-law eminent domain power. Some States enacted statutes allowing the taking of property for the purpose of building private roads. See Lewis §167, at 230. These statutes were mixed; some required the private landowner to keep the road open to the public, and others did not. See id., §167, at 230234. Later in the 19th century, moreover, the Mill Acts were employed to grant rights to private manufacturing plants, in addition to grist mills that had common-carrier duties. See, e.g., M. Horwitz, The Transformation of American Law 17801860, pp. 5152 (1977).
These early uses of the eminent domain power are often cited as evidence for the broad public purpose interpretation of the Public Use Clause, see, e.g., ante, at 8, n. 8 (majority opinion); Brief for Respondents 30; Brief for American Planning Assn. et al. as Amici Curiae at 67, but in fact the constitutionality of these exercises of eminent domain power under state public use restrictions was a hotly contested question in state courts throughout the 19th and into the 20th century. Some courts construed those clauses to authorize takings for public purposes, but others adhered to the natural meaning of public use.2 As noted above, the earliest Mill Acts were applied to entities with duties to remain open to the public, and their later extension is not deeply probative of whether that subsequent practice is consistent with the original meaning of the Public Use Clause. See McIntyre v. Ohio Elections Commn, 514 U.S. 334, 370 (1995) (Thomas, J., concurring in judgment). At the time of the founding, [b]usiness corporations were only beginning to upset the old corporate model, in which the raison dętre of chartered associations was their service to the public, Horwitz, supra, at 4950, so it was natural to those who framed the first Public Use Clauses to think of mills as inherently public entities. The disagreement among state courts, and state legislatures attempts to circumvent public use limits on their eminent domain power, cannot obscure that the Public Use Clause is most naturally read to authorize takings for public use only if the government or the public actually uses the taken property.
III
Our current Public Use Clause jurisprudence, as the Court notes, has rejected this natural reading of the Clause. Ante, at 810. The Court adopted its modern reading blindly, with little discussion of the Clauses history and original meaning, in two distinct lines of cases: first, in cases adopting the public purpose interpretation of the Clause, and second, in cases deferring to legislatures judgments regarding what constitutes a valid public purpose. Those questionable cases converged in the boundlessly broad and deferential conception of public use adopted by this Court in Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26 (1954), and Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229 (1984), cases that take center stage in the Courts opinion. See ante, 1012. The weakness of those two lines of cases, and consequently Berman and Midkiff, fatally undermines the doctrinal foundations of the Courts decision. Todays questionable application of these cases is further proof that the public purpose standard is not susceptible of principled application. This Courts reliance by rote on this standard is ill advised and should be reconsidered.
A
As the Court notes, the public purpose interpretation of the Public Use Clause stems from Fallbrook Irrigation Dist. v. Bradley, 164 U.S. 112, 161162 (1896). Ante, at 11. The issue in Bradley was whether a condemnation for purposes of constructing an irrigation ditch was for a public use. 164 U.S., at 161. This was a public use, Justice Peckham declared for the Court, because [t]o irrigate and thus to bring into possible cultivation these large masses of otherwise worthless lands would seem to be a public purpose and a matter of public interest, not confined to landowners, or even to any one section of the State. Ibid. That broad statement was dictum, for the law under review also provided that [a]ll landowners in the district have the right to a proportionate share of the water. Id., at 162. Thus, the public did have the right to use the irrigation ditch because all similarly situated members of the publicthose who owned lands irrigated by the ditchhad a right to use it. The Court cited no authority for its dictum, and did not discuss either the Public Use Clauses original meaning or the numerous authorities that had adopted the actual use test (though it at least acknowledged the conflict of authority in state courts, see id., at 158; supra, at 9, and n. 2). Instead, the Court reasoned that [t]he use must be regarded as a public use, or else it would seem to follow that no general scheme of irrigation can be formed or carried into effect. Bradley, supra, at 160161. This is no statement of constitutional principle: Whatever the utility of irrigation districts or the merits of the Courts view that another rule would be impractical given the diverse and always evolving needs of society, ante, at 8, the Constitution does not embody those policy preferences any more than it enact[s] Mr. Herbert Spencers Social Statics. Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45, 75 (1905) (Holmes, J., dissenting); but see id., at 5862 (Peckham, J., for the Court).
This Courts cases followed Bradleys test with little analysis. In Clark v. Nash, 198 U.S. 361 (1905) (Peckham, J., for the Court), this Court relied on little more than a citation to Bradley in upholding another condemnation for the purpose of laying an irrigation ditch. 198 U.S., at 369370. As in Bradley, use of the public purpose test was unnecessary to the result the Court reached. The government condemned the irrigation ditch for the purpose of ensuring access to water in which [o]ther land owners adjoining the defendant in error might share, 198 U.S., at 370, and therefore Clark also involved a condemnation for the purpose of ensuring access to a resource to which similarly situated members of the public had a legal right of access. Likewise, in Strickley v. Highland Boy Gold Mining Co., 200 U.S. 527 (1906), the Court upheld a condemnation establishing an aerial right-of-way for a bucket line operated by a mining company, relying on little more than Clark, see Strickley, supra, at 531. This case, too, could have been disposed of on the narrower ground that the plaintiff [was] a carrier for itself and others, 200 U.S., at 531532, and therefore that the bucket line was legally open to the public. Instead, the Court unnecessarily rested its decision on the inadequacy of use by the general public as a universal test. Id., at 531. This Courts cases quickly incorporated the public purpose standard set forth in Clark and Strickley by barren citation. See, e.g., Rindge Co. v. County of Los Angeles, 262 U.S. 700, 707 (1923); Block v. Hirsh, 256 U.S. 135, 155 (1921); Mt. Vernon-Woodberry Cotton Duck Co. v. Alabama Interstate Power Co., 240 U.S. 30, 32 (1916); ONeill v. Leamer, 239 U.S. 244, 253 (1915).
B
A second line of this Courts cases also deviated from the Public Use Clauses original meaning by allowing legislatures to define the scope of valid public uses. United States v. Gettysburg Electric R. Co., 160 U.S. 668 (1896), involved the question whether Congress decision to condemn certain private land for the purpose of building battlefield memorials at Gettysburg, Pennsylvania, was for a public use. Id., at 679680. Since the Federal Government was to use the lands in question, id., at 682, there is no doubt that it was a public use under any reasonable standard. Nonetheless, the Court, speaking through Justice Peckham, declared that when the legislature has declared the use or purpose to be a public one, its judgment will be respected by the courts, unless the use be palpably without reasonable foundation. Id., at 680. As it had with the public purpose dictum in Bradley, supra, the Court quickly incorporated this dictum into its Public Use Clause cases with little discussion. See, e.g., United States ex rel. TVA v. Welch, 327 U.S. 546, 552 (1946); Old Dominion Land Co. v. United States, 269 U.S. 55, 66 (1925).
There is no justification, however, for affording almost insurmountable deference to legislative conclusions that a use serves a public use. To begin with, a court owes no deference to a legislatures judgment concerning the quintessentially legal question of whether the government owns, or the public has a legal right to use, the taken property. Even under the public purpose interpretation, moreover, it is most implausible that the Framers intended to defer to legislatures as to what satisfies the Public Use Clause, uniquely among all the express provisions of the Bill of Rights. We would not defer to a legislatures determination of the various circumstances that establish, for example, when a search of a home would be reasonable, see, e.g., Payton v. New York, 445 U.S. 573, 589590 (1980), or when a convicted double-murderer may be shackled during a sentencing proceeding without on-the-record findings, see Deck v. Missouri, 544 U.S. ___ (2005), or when state law creates a property interest protected by the Due Process Clause, see, e.g., Castle Rock v. Gonzales, post, at __; Board of Regents of State Colleges v. Roth, 408 U.S. 564, 576 (1972); Goldberg v. Kelly, 397 U.S. 254, 262263 (1970).
Still worse, it is backwards to adopt a searching standard of constitutional review for nontraditional property interests, such as welfare benefits, see, e.g., Goldberg, supra, while deferring to the legislatures determination as to what constitutes a public use when it exercises the power of eminent domain, and thereby invades individuals traditional rights in real property. The Court has elsewhere recognized the overriding respect for the sanctity of the home that has been embedded in our traditions since the origins of the Republic, Payton, supra, at 601, when the issue is only whether the government may search a home. Yet today the Court tells us that we are not to second-guess the Citys considered judgments, ante, at 18, when the issue is, instead, whether the government may take the infinitely more intrusive step of tearing down petitioners homes. Something has gone seriously awry with this Courts interpretation of the Constitution. Though citizens are safe from the government in their homes, the homes themselves are not. Once one accepts, as the Court at least nominally does, ante, at 6, that the Public Use Clause is a limit on the eminent domain power of the Federal Government and the States, there is no justification for the almost complete deference it grants to legislatures as to what satisfies it.
C
These two misguided lines of precedent converged in Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26 (1954), and Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229 (1984). Relying on those lines of cases, the Court in Berman and Midkiff upheld condemnations for the purposes of slum clearance and land redistribution, respectively. Subject to specific constitutional limitations, Berman proclaimed, when the legislature has spoken, the public interest has been declared in terms well-nigh conclusive. In such cases the legislature, not the judiciary, is the main guardian of the public needs to be served by social legislation. 348 U.S., at 32. That reasoning was question begging, since the question to be decided was whether the specific constitutional limitation of the Public Use Clause prevented the taking of the appellants (concededly nonblighted) department store. Id., at 31, 34. Berman also appeared to reason that any exercise by Congress of an enumerated power (in this case, its plenary power over the District of Columbia) was per se a public use under the Fifth Amendment. Id., at 33. But the very point of the Public Use Clause is to limit that power. See supra, at 34.
More fundamentally, Berman and Midkiff erred by equating the eminent domain power with the police power of States. See Midkiff, 467 U.S., at 240 (The public use requirement is coterminous with the scope of a sovereigns police powers); Berman, 348 U.S., at 32. Traditional uses of that regulatory power, such as the power to abate a nuisance, required no compensation whatsoever, see Mugler v. Kansas, 123 U.S. 623, 668669 (1887), in sharp contrast to the takings power, which has always required compensation, see supra, at 3, and n. 1. The question whether the State can take property using the power of eminent domain is therefore distinct from the question whether it can regulate property pursuant to the police power. See, e.g., Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1014 (1992); Mugler, supra, at 668669. In Berman, for example, if the slums at issue were truly blighted, then state nuisance law, see, e.g., supra, at 56; Lucas, supra, at 1029, not the power of eminent domain, would provide the appropriate remedy. To construe the Public Use Clause to overlap with the States police power conflates these two categories.3
The public purpose test applied by Berman and Midkiff also cannot be applied in principled manner. When we depart from the natural import of the term public use, and substitute for the simple idea of a public possession and occupation, that of public utility, public interest, common benefit, general advantage or convenience we are afloat without any certain principle to guide us. Bloodgood v. Mohawk & Hudson R. Co., 18 Wend. 9, 6061 (NY 1837) (opinion of Tracy, Sen.). Once one permits takings for public purposes in addition to public uses, no coherent principle limits what could constitute a valid public useat least, none beyond Justice OConnors (entirely proper) appeal to the text of the Constitution itself. See ante, at 12, 813 (dissenting opinion). I share the Courts skepticism about a public use standard that requires courts to second-guess the policy wisdom of public works projects. Ante, at 1619. The public purpose standard this Court has adopted, however, demands the use of such judgment, for the Court concedes that the Public Use Clause would forbid a purely private taking. Ante, at 78. It is difficult to imagine how a court could find that a taking was purely private except by determining that the taking did not, in fact, rationally advance the public interest. Cf. ante, at 910 (OConnor, J., dissenting) (noting the complicated inquiry the Courts test requires). The Court is therefore wrong to criticize the actual use test as difficult to administer. Ante, at 8. It is far easier to analyze whether the government owns or the public has a legal right to use the taken property than to ask whether the taking has a purely private purposeunless the Court means to eliminate public use scrutiny of takings entirely. Ante, at 78, 1617. Obliterating a provision of the Constitution, of course, guarantees that it will not be misapplied.
For all these reasons, I would revisit our Public Use Clause cases and consider returning to the original meaning of the Public Use Clause: that the government may take property only if it actually uses or gives the public a legal right to use the property.
IV
The consequences of todays decision are not difficult to predict, and promise to be harmful. So-called urban renewal programs provide some compensation for the properties they take, but no compensation is possible for the subjective value of these lands to the individuals displaced and the indignity inflicted by uprooting them from their homes. Allowing the government to take property solely for public purposes is bad enough, but extending the concept of public purpose to encompass any economically beneficial goal guarantees that these losses will fall disproportionately on poor communities. Those communities are not only systematically less likely to put their lands to the highest and best social use, but are also the least politically powerful. If ever there were justification for intrusive judicial review of constitutional provisions that protect discrete and insular minorities, United States v. Carolene Products Co., 304 U.S. 144, 152, n. 4 (1938), surely that principle would apply with great force to the powerless groups and individuals the Public Use Clause protects. The deferential standard this Court has adopted for the Public Use Clause is therefore deeply perverse. It encourages those citizens with dis- proportionate influence and power in the political pro- cess, including large corporations and development firms to victimize the weak. Ante, at 11 (OConnor, J., dissenting).
Those incentives have made the legacy of this Courts public purpose test an unhappy one. In the 1950s, no doubt emboldened in part by the expansive understanding of public use this Court adopted in Berman, cities rushed to draw plans for downtown development. B. Frieden & L. Sagalayn, Downtown, Inc. How America Rebuilds Cities 17 (1989). Of all the families displaced by urban renewal from 1949 through 1963, 63 percent of those whose race was known were nonwhite, and of these families, 56 percent of nonwhites and 38 percent of whites had incomes low enough to qualify for public housing, which, however, was seldom available to them. Id., at 28. Public works projects in the 1950s and 1960s destroyed predominantly minority communities in St. Paul, Minnesota, and Baltimore, Maryland. Id., at 2829. In 1981, urban planners in Detroit, Michigan, uprooted the largely lower-income and elderly Poletown neighborhood for the benefit of the General Motors Corporation. J. Wylie, Poletown: Community Betrayed 58 (1989). Urban renewal projects have long been associated with the displacement of blacks; [i]n cities across the country, urban renewal came to be known as Negro removal. Pritchett, The Public Menace of Blight: Urban Renewal and the Private Uses of Eminent Domain, 21 Yale L. & Poly Rev. 1, 47 (2003). Over 97 percent of the individuals forcibly removed from their homes by the slum-clearance project upheld by this Court in Berman were black. 348 U.S., at 30. Regrettably, the predictable consequence of the Courts decision will be to exacerbate these effects.
***
The Court relies almost exclusively on this Courts prior cases to derive todays far-reaching, and dangerous, result. See ante, at 812. But the principles this Court should employ to dispose of this case are found in the Public Use Clause itself, not in Justice Peckhams high opinion of reclamation laws, see supra, at 11. When faced with a clash of constitutional principle and a line of unreasoned cases wholly divorced from the text, history, and structure of our founding document, we should not hesitate to resolve the tension in favor of the Constitutions original meaning. For the reasons I have given, and for the reasons given in Justice OConnors dissent, the conflict of principle raised by this boundless use of the eminent domain power should be resolved in petitioners favor. I would reverse the judgment of the Connecticut Supreme Court.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Notes 1. Some state constitutions at the time of the founding lacked just compensation clauses and took property even without providing compensation. See Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 10561057 (1992) (Blackmun, J., dissenting). The Framers of the Fifth Amendment apparently disagreed, for they expressly prohibited uncompensated takings, and the Fifth Amendment was not incorporated against the States until much later. See id., at 1028, n. 15.
2. Compare ante, at 8, and n. 8 (majority opinion) (noting that some state courts upheld the validity of applying the Mill Acts to private purposes and arguing that the use by the public test eroded over time), with, e.g., Ryerson v. Brown, 35 Mich. 333, 338339 (1877) (holding it essential to the constitutionality of a Mill Act that the statute should require the use to be public in fact; in other words, that it should contain provisions entitling the public to accommodations); Gaylord v. Sanitary Dist. of Chicago, 204 Ill. 576, 581584, 68 N. E. 522, 524 (1903) (same); Tyler v. Beacher, 44 Vt. 648, 652656 (1871) (same); Sadler v. Langham, 34 Ala. 311, 332334 (1859) (striking down taking for purely private road and grist mill); Varner v. Martin, 21 W. Va. 534, 546548, 556557, 566567 (1883) (grist mill and private road had to be open to public for them to constitute public use); Harding v. Goodlett, 3 Yerg. 41, 53 (1832); Jacobs v. Clearview Water Supply Co., 220 Pa. 388, 393395, 69 A. 870, 872 (1908) (endorsing actual public use standard); Minnesota Canal & Power Co. v. Koochiching Co., 97 Minn. 429, 449451, 107 N. W. 405, 413 (1906) (same); Chesapeake Stone Co. v. Moreland, 126 Ky. 656, 663667, 104 S. W. 762, 765 (Ct. App. 1907) (same); Note, Public Use in Eminent Domain, 21 N. Y. U. L. Q. Rev. 285, 286, and n. 11 (1946) (calling the actual public use standard the majority view and citing other cases).
3. Some States also promoted the alienability of property by abolishing the feudal quit rent system, i.e., long-term leases under which the proprietor reserved to himself the right to perpetual payment of rents from his tenant. See Vance, The Quest for Tenure in the United States, 33 Yale L. J. 248, 256257, 260263 (1923). In Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229 (1984), the Court cited those state policies favoring the alienability of land as evidence that the governments eminent domain power was similarly expansive, see id., at 241242, and n. 5. But they were uses of the States regulatory power, not the takings power, and therefore were irrelevant to the issue in Midkiff. This mismatch underscores the error of conflating a States regulatory power with its taking power.
Thank you so much for posting this; it's so refreshing to read what Justice Thomas has to say. Is there any doubt that he may indeed be the ONLY choice for a new Chief Justice position? Sorry Scalia fans -- I'm a Thomas man.
I concur - this session Thomas has shown himself to be the choice for Chief Justice + Dubya would do well to further his father's choice :)
This may help slow down the liberal trend to citing foreign precedents in US decisions.
It cuts both ways.
If they want to cite the International Court of Wussiedom on the death penalty, we can cite Hamurabi on the same.
So9
I am a big fan of both men, but I want the Chief Justice to be Clarence Thomas.
If only because it would make such a nice bookend to the nasty confirmation process he endured.
yoo-hoo...
Seriously, Judge Thomas deserves to be the next Chief Justice.
Thanks- I hadn't seen this yet. Today is a dark day for America, and Americans of all stripes.
This reminds me of the time, several years ago, when my sons and I went to Chilies restaurant on a Saturday afternoon. We were seated at a booth. We had just gotten our food (the fajitas are great when you get a good batch), when a couple and a little kid were seated at a booth right next to us. I glanced over, and had to take a double take. Was that who I thought it was? Then the man laughed, and that was the conformation, we are having lunch with Justice Clarence Thomas!
I had, for several years, had my oldest son watch Justice Thomas whenever he would make speeches on C-Span. I would explain to him that this was a good strong man. After a few years, my son started to inform me when Justice Thomas was on TV. His intelligence and down to earth demeanor always inspired us.
I leaned over to my son, as he was gobbling down his nachos and asked him if he recognized who was at the next table. His eyes grew wide and glassy, his face turned red and he said its
its
its.. And I said thats right, isnt it fun living in Fairfax Virginia? My son didnt eat much after that. Well we were almost finished, and the table was cleaned and we were waiting for the check. I knew that this was it, and I had to say something. I turned toward his table and said Justice Thomas. He looked over at me, with a look of surprise, and I then said When are you going to convince your associates to actually read the Constitution, and enforce the 10th amendment?. There was a seconds pause, where you get to reflect about what a fool you are potentially creating of yourself. And then it happened, Justice Thomas laughed, that big resounding laugh. I made Clarence Thomas laugh, how cool is that?
We talked for a few moments. For some reason the subject of C-Span came up. Justice Thomas related how he was watching C-Span that morning, and how this crabby woman called, and was complaining about how the government should be doing all of these things like health care and saving the environment, etcetera. After the woman was done with her tirade, the moderator of the show told the woman that she should call here congressperson and senators. The moderator then asked the woman who her representatives are. And the woman did not know! We all had a good laugh over this.
About that time, their food came, so we shook hands, and bid them goodbye. I told the boys to meet me at the front of the restaurant in a few moments, as I swung around to the kitchen area, and told the waiter I wanted to pay the tab and tip for the booth next to us. The transaction was processed, and we left. As we walked to the car, my son asked me what I had done while they were waiting for me. I said I just bought lunch for Supreme Court Justice Clarence Thomas. Thus I went up several points in my cool dad status that day.
After a couple of hours, I went back to the restaurant and asked the waiter what had happened after we left. He said Justice Thomas was at a loss for words when told that someone had paid for their lunch. The waiter said he just kept on repeating Thank you, Thank you over and over again.
True story.
Ps
Justice Thomas ordered Buffalo wings as an appetizer. I cant remember what his entrée was, sorry.
Figured you'd want it.
The Court has elsewhere recognized "the overriding respect for the sanctity of the home that has been embedded in our traditions since the origins of the Republic," Payton, supra, at 601, when the issue is only whether the government may search a home. Yet today the Court tells us that we are not to "second-guess the City's considered judgments," ante, at 18, when the issue is, instead, whether the government may take the infinitely more intrusive step of tearing down petitioners' homes. Something has gone seriously awry with this Court's interpretation of the Constitution. Though citizens are safe from the government in their homes, the homes themselves are not. Once one accepts, as the Court at least nominally does, ante, at 6, that the Public Use Clause is a limit on the eminent domain power of the Federal Government and the States, there is no justification for the almost complete deference it grants to legislatures as to what satisfies it.
He is exactly right. What good is a right to privacy IN my home if the government can just take the home itself??
Absolutely, and thanks again.
Is it now fair to ask if Harry can read???
Yup, I concur with your son - you're a cool dad!
Awesome story - thanks for posting it.
Is bold on?
</b>
See if this turns it off...
This is the same sort of debate going on with Social Security. Private accounts would be the property of the individual, not the tenuous future promise of our elected representatives.
Great story. Lucky.
Thomas and O'Connor wonder who else dissented?
Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.