Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

Skip to comments.

When it goes wrong...
The Economist ^ | 20 Sep 2007 | Economist

Posted on 09/22/2007 7:26:41 AM PDT by oblomov

“THE medium-term outlook for the company is very positive,” declared Northern Rock's chief executive, Adam Applegarth, unveiling its first-half results in July. He spoke of a credit book that was “robust”. Who would have guessed that less than two months later Britain's fifth-largest mortgage lender would be fighting for its life, its branches besieged by customers demanding their savings back?

The run on Northern Rock is the most dramatic symptom of the contagion gripping the financial markets. Here was a bank that had grown rich from the innovations of recent years, using abundantly stocked wholesale markets to fund its lively growth, using those same markets to offload bits of its loan book as and when they became unattractive.

But the very innovations on which Northern Rock thrived have savaged its business. The company does no lending to speak of overseas. Nevertheless, its fate was determined by the distant turmoil in America's mortgage market. When that spilled over into the securities markets, the money markets that Northern Rock had depended on for years dried up in a single day at the start of August.

The brave new world that enabled banks like Northern Rock to grow so fast is founded on “securitisation”—the process that transforms mortgages, credit-card receivables and other financial assets into marketable securities—and the innovation it spawned in “structured” products. This was a revolution that brought huge gains. But across the financial world investors and regulators are asking themselves whether it also brought costs that are only now becoming clear.

Investigations begin

In America the President's Working Group on Financial Markets, which includes the Federal Reserve and the Treasury, has launched a probe into securitisation and the rating agencies, which monitor it. IOSCO, a global regulators' body, has begun an investigation of its own.

(Excerpt) Read more at economist.com ...


TOPICS: Business/Economy; Front Page News; News/Current Events
KEYWORDS: cdo; debt; economy; fanniemae; freddiemac; ginniemae; securitization
How could an entire article on the CDO/CLO blowup be written without touching upon the role of GSEs such as Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and Sallie Mae? The implicit government guarantee of GSE-backed debt is what made these vehicles so attractive and ostensibly low-risk.
1 posted on 09/22/2007 7:26:42 AM PDT by oblomov
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | View Replies]

To: oblomov

The most likely reason is because Northern Rock offers mortgages in the UK only.


2 posted on 09/22/2007 7:41:00 AM PDT by proxy_user
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: oblomov

House of (credit) cards!


3 posted on 09/22/2007 7:41:31 AM PDT by norraad ("What light!">Blues Brothers)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: oblomov; Admin Moderator
“How could an entire article on the CDO/CLO blowup be written without touching upon the role of GSEs such as Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and Sallie Mae? The implicit government guarantee of GSE-backed debt is what made these vehicles so attractive and ostensibly low-risk.”

I agree, they should have mentioned them, but overall the article was an excellent explanation of how mortgage risk got separated from the mortgage holders.

Please explain “implicit government guarantee”. I am not familiar with the government’s role in Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and Sallie Mae. I just know they are large debt wholesalers. It seems “implicit guarantee” is a contradiction. If it is a guarantee, then it is explicit. If it is implicit, then it’s not a guarantee.

I’ve posted entire articles from the Economist before; is there any reason this has to be excerpted?

Admin Moderator, please delete the rest of this post if we must excerpt from the Economist.

The run on Northern Rock is the most dramatic symptom of the contagion gripping the financial markets. Here was a bank that had grown rich from the innovations of recent years, using abundantly stocked wholesale markets to fund its lively growth, using those same markets to offload bits of its loan book as and when they became unattractive.

But the very innovations on which Northern Rock thrived have savaged its business. The company does no lending to speak of overseas. Nevertheless, its fate was determined by the distant turmoil in America’s mortgage market. When that spilled over into the securities markets, the money markets that Northern Rock had depended on for years dried up in a single day at the start of August.

The brave new world that enabled banks like Northern Rock to grow so fast is founded on “securitisation”—the process that transforms mortgages, credit-card receivables and other financial assets into marketable securities—and the innovation it spawned in “structured” products. This was a revolution that brought huge gains. But across the financial world investors and regulators are asking themselves whether it also brought costs that are only now becoming clear.
Investigations begin

In America the President’s Working Group on Financial Markets, which includes the Federal Reserve and the Treasury, has launched a probe into securitisation and the rating agencies, which monitor it. IOSCO, a global regulators’ body, has begun an investigation of its own. And the two biggest securitisation clubs on either side of the Atlantic held an emergency summit this week to look for ways to coax investors back into moribund asset-backed markets.

It is hard to overstate the extent of this reversal in fortunes, if only because it is hard to overstate the effect that securitisation has had on financial markets. Until the early 1980s, finance hewed to an “originate and hold” model. Banks generally held loans on their balance sheets to maturity; some debts were sold on loan-by-loan, but this market was small and lumpy. This began to give way to an “originate and distribute” model after America’s government-sponsored mortgage giants issued the first bonds with payments tied to the cash flows from large pools of loans.

Wall Street built on this innovation, and securitisation took off soon after, then paused before exploding in the 1990s (see chart 1). It was given a lift by America’s savings-and-loan crisis, which encouraged mortgage lenders to jettison their riskier loans, and by new technologies, such as credit-scoring, that facilitated loan-pooling. Around 56% of America’s outstanding residential mortgages were packaged in this way, including more than two-thirds of the subprime loans issued in 2006. Thanks largely to securitisation, global private-debt securities are now far bigger than stockmarkets.

Banks have come to see securitisation as an indispensable tool (see chart 2). Global lenders use it to manage their balance sheets, since selling loans frees up capital for new business or for return to shareholders. Small regional banks benefit too. Gone are the days when they had no choice but to place concentrated bets on local housing markets or industry. Now they can offload credits to far-away investors such as insurers and hedge funds, which have an appetite for them.

Michael Milken, of junk-bond fame, called securitisation the “democratisation of capital”. Studies suggest that the explosion of this “secondary” market for bank debt has helped to push down borrowing costs for consumers and companies alike. There are other “systemic” gains, too. Subjecting bank loans to valuation by capital markets encourages the efficient use of capital. And the broad distribution of credit risk reduces the risk of any one holder going bust.

Even in the midst of turmoil, it is hard to find a banker, regulator or academic who wants to see the clock turned back. But the crisis has exposed cracks in the new model that were hidden or ignored during the credit bubble. The three most glaring are complexity and confusion, a fragmentation of responsibility and the gaming of the regulatory system. Take each in turn.
Too clever by 50 basis points

The past few weeks have shown that financiers did not fully understand what they were trading. The boom in derivatives was one of those moments when financial engineering raced ahead of back offices and risk-management departments, leaving them struggling to value or account for their holdings. Pierre Pourquery, of Boston Consulting Group, says it is not uncommon for investors to break their exotic purchases into smaller pieces in order to feed them into their risk-management systems. This brings new risks, particularly that the parts will behave differently from the whole under stress.

Steven Schwarcz, a professor at Duke University and writer on securitisation, has come across contracts which are so convoluted that it would be impractical for investors to try to understand them: they would have to spend more money hiring experts to deconstruct them than they could ever hope to earn in extra returns.

In a recent paper* on credit derivatives, David Skeel and Frank Partnoy concluded that collateralised debt obligations (CDOs), one of the most common derivatives, are too clever by half. The transaction costs are high, the benefits questionable. They conclude that CDOs are being used to transform existing debt instruments that are accurately priced into new ones that are overvalued.

Complexity confuses investors about the risks they are taking on. The more eclectic CDOs bind together the fate of assets that have few real economic links. Imagine a lowly rated energy bond and top-notch bank paper in the same structure. Separately, they would not normally move in tandem. Put them in a CDO, however, and in a credit squeeze they fall together, by virtue of being in the same murky structure, as investors rush for the exit or seek to hedge their risks.

The lack of transparency plagues the bundling of loans into securities, too. These days, for instance, lenders are less likely to foreclose on defaulting borrowers: in America, less than a quarter of loans 90 days late or more are in foreclosure, compared with three-quarters in the late 1990s, points out Charles Calomiris, of Columbia University. When a late payer gets back on track his loan is once again labelled “current”, and his chequered history does not have to be fully disclosed when the loan goes into a securitised pool. So even the most diligent buyer would struggle to spot that some of the “prime” collateral of mortgage-backed bonds was, in fact, of questionable quality.

Investors seeking redress have encountered unforeseen problems. Securitisations are generally structured as “true sales”: the seller wipes its hands of the risk. In practice buyers have some protection. Many contracts allow them to hand back loan pools that sour surprisingly quickly. Some have done just this with the most rancid subprime mortgages, requesting an injection of better-quality loans into the pool. But there were so many bad loans that originators could not oblige. “What we thought was an effective secondary-market punishment mechanism turns out to be faulty when the problem grows beyond a certain size,” says Anthony Sanders, a subprime expert.

The second lesson of the past few weeks is that securitisation has warped financiers’ incentives. It is sometimes portrayed as bank “disintermediation”, but in fact it replaces one middleman with several. In mortgage securitisation, for instance, the lender is supplanted by the broker, the loan originator, the servicer (who collects payments), the investor and the arranger, not to mention the rating agencies and mortgage-bond insurers.

This creates what economists call a principal-agent problem. The loan originator has little incentive to vet borrowers carefully because it knows the risk will soon be off its books. The ultimate holder of the risk, the investor, has more reason to care but owns a complex product and is too far down the chain for monitoring to work. For all its flaws, the old bank model resolved the incentives in a simple way. Because loans were kept in-house, banks had every reason both to underwrite cautiously and also to keep tabs on the borrower after the money left the vault.

Investors in loan-backed securities could have pushed for tougher monitoring. But most were too taken with the alluring yields on offer—an addiction Alan Greenspan, the Fed’s former chairman, has likened to cocaine abuse. Debt investors are usually sober types, but as the bubble grew, it was increasingly their urges, and not the creditworthiness of homeowners, that determined loan-underwriting standards.

Wall Street took full advantage of this appetite. It was well known that investors such as Germany’s IKB, a lender to small companies which was bailed out last month, had a weakness for exotic products. The securities firms peddling mortgage-backed bonds did little to disabuse them of the notion that a CDO with a high rating must be as safe as houses—after all, the buyers were sophisticated institutions, not widows or orphans.

Moreover Wall Street has every reason to shovel securitised debt out as fast as it can. The loan-origination platform has high fixed costs, so it is a scale business. This can lead to trouble when there are not enough creditworthy new borrowers, as in subprime lending. Banks may be tempted to keep feeding the machine at the expense of laxer lending standards. “Once you get into it, it’s a bit like heroin,” says Joseph Mason, an academic who has written on securitisation. When AAA paper is repeatedly compared to Class A drugs, you know something is wrong.
Rating the raters

Complexity and warped incentives foster the third cost of securitisation: gaming the regulations. Politicians are scrutinising the role of rating agencies, as they did with auditors after the dotcom bubble burst. Regulatory dependence on ratings has grown across the board. Banks can reduce the amount of capital they have to set aside if they hold highly rated paper, for instance, and some investors, such as money-market funds, must stick to AAA-rated securities. But not all top-rated paper is the same.

The agencies appear to have been too free in giving out prized AAA badges to structured products, especially CDOs. This was partly because their models were faulty, failing to pick up correlations between different markets, and partly because of a conflict of interest: theirs is one of few businesses where the appraiser is paid by the seller, not the buyer.

This made it easier for the banks securitising and further repackaging debt to create the greatest possible number of securities with the lowest regulatory cost (that is, highest rating). Investors restricted to investment-grade paper assumed (or at least hoped) that the rating was a guarantee of strength. It might have helped if the agencies had properly monitored their ratings after issuing them. But with low fees per security there is little incentive to stay on the case.
AFP From dodgy American mortgages to the British high street

Avinash Persaud, of Intelligence Capital, a consultancy, argues that securitisation has let banks (as regulated “holders” of credit risk, with the capacity to keep it through bad times) pass it on to unregulated “traders” of risk with smaller balance sheets, such as hedge funds, which sell when trouble strikes. As a result, he says, although the risk of bank runs has fallen, the risk of market runs has increased.

In fact, some hedge funds are patient investors in illiquid assets. But Mr Persaud is right that risk changes, chameleon-like, depending on the holder. A bank with a plump capital cushion can use its balance sheet to hold on to out-of-favour credits until markets regain their balance. An investment fund that is several steps removed from the borrower, vulnerable to margin calls and constrained by daily risk models will have less room for manoeuvre. The rise of such investors has led, paradoxically, to more of a herd mentality because of “convergence in the way risk has been diversified”, says Mr Schwarcz.

Fans of securitisation argue that it has made the system safer, because risk ends up with those who want to shoulder it. It is true that few banks have failed in recent years, in spite of the Asian crisis, the failure of Long-Term Capital Management, the dotcom bust and so forth. But this could have more to do with economic stability than securitisation.

Indeed, André Cappon, a consultant, warns of the “circularity of risk”. The hedge funds that buy mortgage-linked debt also borrow heavily from the prime-brokerage arms of banks that originated many of the underlying loans. So a bank can push risk out of the front door, only to find it sneaking through the back.
Shine a light

What should banks and regulators do about all this? In the short run, the focus will be on transparency. Investors need to know who is holding what and how should it be valued. One idea is to force investment banks to reveal more about the performance and price of privately traded asset-backed instruments. Another is for the Securities and Exchange Commission, Wall Street’s main regulator, to ensure consistent valuation of such assets across firms. More information on the vehicles that issue asset-backed commercial paper would also help.

There will also be calls for greater standardisation of structured products. This could undermine the “over the counter” (off-exchange) markets. Exchange groups like the Chicago Mercantile Exchange and Deutsche Börse have been trying to take business away from the banks, offering centrally cleared foreign-exchange trading and credit products. Regulators like these because they are more transparent than privately traded deals. The crisis could tip the balance in the exchanges’ favour, says Benn Steil, a market-watcher at the Council on Foreign Relations.

If investors continue to shun the most complex products, Wall Street will have to offer simpler fare. Tom Zimmerman, head of asset-backed research at UBS, sees parallels between the CDO bust and the blow-up in collateralised mortgage obligations (CMOs) in the mid-1990s. CMOs, which pool prepayment risk, became so convoluted that investors could no longer see where the dangers lay. When they stopped buying, investment banks made the product more straightforward and it took off again.

As for the rating agencies, they have probably grown more powerful than anyone intended. Regulators will want to see their interests aligned more closely with investors, and to ensure that they are quicker and more thorough in reviewing past ratings. Moody’s is thinking about adding new letter codes to cover liquidity and volatility risk for complex products.

Fixing the problem of fragmented responsibility will be a balancing act. Mr Sanders thinks subprime default rates would not have spiked if loan originators had been forced to set aside capital to cover, say, 10% of each securitised pool. But framing the terms of this sort of co-insurance would be tricky. Would 10% be enough? Or too much? Should a reputable bank have to pay as much as a small specialist-lender?

With investors, too, there is a risk of heavy-handedness. Calls for federal legislation on “assignee liability”, which would hold secondary-market investors liable for loan losses, could do more harm than good. The soul-searching has led some analysts to speculate that mortgage lending could, for a time, go back to being a bank-led lend-and-hold market.

But do not expect a rush back to the ways of the 1960s. Securitisation has become far too important for that. Indeed, it has not yet fulfilled its promise. Wall Street eggheads may be licking their wounds at present, but they will soon be coming up with even more products. And, given time, there will no doubt be another wave of buying. More importantly, the transformation of sticky debt into something more tradable, for all its imperfections, has forged hugely beneficial links between individual borrowers and vast capital markets that were previously out of reach. As it comes under scrutiny, the debate should be about how this system can be improved, not dismantled.

* “The Promise and Perils of Credit Derivatives”, by David Skeel and Frank Partnoy, University of Cincinnati Law Review, 2006

4 posted on 09/22/2007 8:21:23 AM PDT by Forgiven_Sinner (Just because 50 million people believe a foolish thing, doesn't mean it isn't foolish.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Forgiven_Sinner
>>Please explain “implicit government guarantee”.

Here goes:

There are mortgage loans that are 100% backed by the government. There is an explicit government guarantee of repayment of these loans. Examples of these are loans issued by the FHA and Department of Veteran's Affairs. These loans are securitized through Ginnie Mae, which is a government-owned corporation within HUD.

Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae are no longer directly owned by the government. They are shareholder owned companies that are considered "government sponsored enterprises". This sponsorship has a complex set of implications. On the one hand, as part of the charter of each GSE, it is required to issue debt in specific geographic areas, issue a certain amount of debt, issue MBS, make a secondary market in MBS, etc. Their charter is ostensibly to stabilize the housing market.

Although there is no guarantee of repayment of these loans as is the case with agency loans, there is a premium paid for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac loans. These loans pay 1/2 to 3/4 of a point less in interest than those of other mortgage originators, even well-capitalized institutions such as Citibank or Goldman Sachs. Why is this the case? It is because there is an implicit government guarantee of these loans. The market believes that if there were any question of the solvency of Fannie or Freddie, that the government would bail out the investors. And the market is probably right.

Consider the fact that Fannie Mae released a 10-K (Annual Financial Report) to the SEC only one month ago, for the first time since 2004! What other NYSE-traded firm could get away with this, without at least being delisted? These "private" companies get very special treatment indeed.

Also consider the recent moves on the part of Congress to expand the scope of lending that Fannie and Freddie can engage in.

These entities are socialist in form, especially when you consider some purposes to which they are used.

But they operate within a market structure- they make the secondary market in MBS. The name for this is corporatism, although I wish there were another word for it, since that term carries implications of JBS and left-wing paranoia.

5 posted on 09/22/2007 8:59:42 AM PDT by oblomov
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 4 | View Replies]

To: oblomov
Thank you for an excellent explanation. No article I’ve read has explained them as well, and I probably read 50-200 financial articles a year.

Yep, I agree with your assessment—they seem to be a form of socialism. I’m a little confused over how the government controls them. How can the government dictate to the private stockholders of these agencies or their management? Is the “charter” a legally binding obligation to follow certain social policies? It seems that once the government “privatized” the agencies it lost control over them.

Also, how do these agencies get away with violating FEC law? That alone raises my hackles.

In all, this sort of socialism seems similar to the Federal Reserve, a blend of private and public institution.

6 posted on 09/22/2007 9:19:32 AM PDT by Forgiven_Sinner (The most incomprehensible thing about the universe is that it is at all comprehensible.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 5 | View Replies]

To: Forgiven_Sinner

A Freeper is quoted in this article!

GNMA MBS consists of FHA-insured mortgages. Clearly, this is a socialist program.

FNMA and FHLMC MBS consist of conforming mortgages originated in an open marketplace. No socialism. One could argue that they receive an implicit subsidy because of the believe that they are too big to fail, but other than that, there is no socialism.

If the Fed behaving in a socialist manner? The Fed is friends of the banking and investment banking industry, but must still try to maintain order. Ron Paul wants to get rid of them and perhaps that is appropriate. But remember your history and what the banking system was like during the depression (bank failures, personal wealth vanishing).


7 posted on 09/22/2007 10:12:35 AM PDT by whitedog57
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 6 | View Replies]

To: oblomov

This one is much better IMO.

http://www.freerepublic.com/focus/f-news/1899312/posts


8 posted on 09/22/2007 10:24:19 AM PDT by GodGunsGuts
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: oblomov
[without touching upon the role of GSEs such as Fannie Mae,]

My understanding is that of the many sub-prime products did not meet guidelines and qualify for GSE backing.

The securitized instruments in question were often insured via private insurance.

9 posted on 09/22/2007 5:51:42 PM PDT by VxH (One if by Land, Two if by Sea, and Three if by Wire Transfer)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: VxH

>>of the many sub-prime products

= many of the sub-prime products


10 posted on 09/22/2007 5:53:09 PM PDT by VxH (One if by Land, Two if by Sea, and Three if by Wire Transfer)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 9 | View Replies]

To: Forgiven_Sinner
The OFHEO, a part of HUD, has as its sole mission the regulation of Fannie and Freddie.

Although they are now private companies, they maintain an relationship with the government that is ambiguous at best. They were privatized by act of Congress, but with the stipulation that they act under a charter that obligates them to, as you say, follow certain social policies. The OFHEO ensures that they are following this charter.

This ambiguous relationship, with its result being that Fannie and Freddie have lower borrowing costs than other mortgage originators, amounts to a taxpayer subsidy of these companies. Acknowledgment of this subsidy is not controversial in itself, since it has been discussed by politicians on both sides of the aisle as well as Allan Greenspan. Critics of the GSEs, such as this organization, which is headed up by none other than former Congressman J.C. Watts, claim that the GSEs misappropriate this subsidy (note: it gets funding from lobbying groups in the mortgage services industry).

Most of the outspoken critics of the GSEs are on the right, for two reasons. First, GSEs are perceived to be a form of government intervention in the economy (even if just implicitly), which creates a systemic risk to the financial system, since the GSEs originate more debt than they would be able to under a free market. Second, the social charter of the GSEs is, though well-intended, redistributive.

I don't know how they get around FEC regulations. Probably by funding so-called non-political activities of these very political activist groups.

11 posted on 09/23/2007 10:26:22 AM PDT by oblomov
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 6 | View Replies]

Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.

Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

FreeRepublic, LLC, PO BOX 9771, FRESNO, CA 93794
FreeRepublic.com is powered by software copyright 2000-2008 John Robinson