Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

Skip to comments.

Milton Friedman: How to cure healthcare
Hoover Digest ^ | 2001 | Milton Friedman

Posted on 03/06/2005 1:59:25 AM PST by Dr. Marten

How to Cure Health Care

Milton Friedman

The United States spends a mind-boggling percentage of its GDP on a health care system that virtually everyone agrees is a disaster. Is there any way out of this mess? There is—and Milton Friedman has found it.

 

Since the end of World War II, the provision of medical care in the United States and other advanced countries has displayed three major features: first, rapid advances in the science of medicine; second, large increases in spending, both in terms of inflation-adjusted dollars per person and the fraction of national income spent on medical care; and third, rising dissatisfaction with the delivery of medical care, on the part of both consumers of medical care and physicians and other suppliers of medical care.

Ilustration by Taylor Jones for the Hoover Digest.

Rapid technological advances have occurred repeatedly since the Industrial Revolution—in agriculture, steam engines, railroads, telephones, electricity, automobiles, radio, television, and, most recently, computers and telecommunication. The other two features seem unique to medicine. It is true that spending initially increased after nonmedical technical advances, but the fraction of national income spent did not increase dramatically after the initial phase of widespread acceptance. On the contrary, technological development lowered cost, so that the fraction of national income spent on food, transportation, communication, and much more has gone down, releasing resources to produce new products or services. Similarly, there seems no counterpart in these other areas to the rising dissatisfaction with the delivery of medical care.

International Comparison

These developments in medicine have been worldwide. By their very nature, scientific advances know no geographic boundaries. Data on spending are readily available for 29 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries. In every one, medical spending has gone up significantly both in inflation-adjusted dollars per person and as a fraction of national income. In 1997, the United States spent 14 percent of gross domestic product on medical care, the highest of any OECD country. Germany was a distant second at 11 percent; Turkey was the lowest at 4 percent.

A key difference between medical care and the other technological revolutions is the role of government. In other technological revolutions, the initiative, financing, production, and distribution were primarily private, though government sometimes played a supporting or regulatory role. In medical care, government has come to play a leading role in financing, producing, and delivering medical service. Direct government spending on health care exceeds 75 percent of total health spending for 15 OECD countries. The United States is next to the lowest of the 29 countries, at 46 percent. In addition, some governments indirectly subsidize medical care through favorable tax treatment. For the United States, such subsidization raises the fraction of health spending financed directly or indirectly by government to more than 50 percent.

What are countries getting for the money they are spending on medical care? What is the relation between input and output? Spending on medical care provides a reasonably good measure of input, but, unfortunately, there is no remotely satisfactory objective measure of output.

Ultimately, the purpose of this article is to examine the situation in the United States. I have mentioned the data on the OECD countries primarily to document the two (related?) respects in which the United States is exceptional: we spend a higher percentage of national income on medical care (and more per capita) than any other OECD country, and our government finances a smaller fraction of that spending than all countries except Korea.

Why Third-Party Payment?

Two simple observations are key to explaining both the high level of spending on medical care and the dissatisfaction with that spending. The first is that most payments to physicians or hospitals or other caregivers for medical care are made not by the patient but by a third party—an insurance company or employer or governmental body. The second is that nobody spends somebody else’s money as wisely or as frugally as he spends his own. These statements apply equally to other OECD countries. They do not by themselves explain why the United States spends so much more than other countries.

No third party is involved when we shop at a supermarket. We pay the supermarket clerk directly: the same for gasoline for our car, clothes for our back, and so on down the line. Why, by contrast, are most medical payments made by third parties? The answer for the United States begins with the fact that medical care expenditures are exempt from the income tax if, and only if, medical care is provided by the employer. If an employee pays directly for medical care, the expenditure comes out of the employee’s after-tax income. If the employer pays for the employee’s medical care, the expenditure is treated as a tax-deductible expense for the employer and is not included as part of the employee’s income subject to income tax. That strong incentive explains why most consumers get their medical care through their employers or their spouses’ or their parents’ employer. In the next place, the enactment of Medicare and Medicaid in 1965 made the government a third-party payer for persons and medical care covered by those measures.

We are headed toward completely socialized medicine—and, if we take indirect tax subsidies into account, we’re already halfway there.

We have become so accustomed to employer-provided medical care that we regard it as part of the natural order. Yet it is thoroughly illogical. Why single out medical care? Food is more essential to life than medical care. Why not exempt the cost of food from taxes if provided by the employer? Why not return to the much-reviled company store when workers were in effect paid in kind rather than in cash?

The revival of the company store for medicine has less to do with logic than pure chance. It is a wonderful example of how one bad government policy leads to another. During World War II, the government financed much wartime spending by printing money while, at the same time, imposing wage and price controls. The resulting repressed inflation produced shortages of many goods and services, including labor. Firms competing to acquire labor at government-controlled wages started to offer medical care as a fringe benefit. That benefit proved particularly attractive to workers and spread rapidly.

Initially, employers did not report the value of the fringe benefit to the Internal Revenue Service as part of their workers’ wages. It took some time before the IRS realized what was going on. When it did, it issued regulations requiring employers to include the value of medical care as part of reported employees’ wages. By this time, workers had become accustomed to the tax exemption of that particular fringe benefit and made a big fuss. Congress responded by legislating that medical care provided by employers should be tax-exempt.

Effect of Third-Party Payment on Medical Costs

The tax exemption of employer-provided medical care has two different effects, both of which raise health costs. First, it leads employees to rely on their employer, rather than themselves, to make arrangements for medical care. Yet employees are likely to do a better job of monitoring medical care providers—because it is in their own interest—than is the employer or the insurance company or companies designated by the employer. Second, it leads employees to take a larger fraction of their total remuneration in the form of medical care than they would if spending on medical care had the same tax status as other expenditures.

If the tax exemption were removed, employees could bargain with their employers for higher take-home pay in lieu of medical care and provide for their own medical care either by dealing directly with medical care providers or by purchasing medical insurance. Removal of the tax exemption would enable governments to reduce the tax rate on income while raising the same total revenue. This hidden subsidy for medical care, currently more than $100 billion a year, is not included in reported figures on government health spending.

Extending the tax exemption to all medical care—as in the current limited provision for medical savings accounts and the proposals to make such accounts more widely available—would reduce reliance on third-party payment. But, by extending the hidden subsidy to all medical care expenditures, it would increase the tendency of employees to take a larger portion of their remuneration in the form of medical care. (I discuss medical savings accounts more fully in the conclusion.)

Expressed as a fraction of national income, Americans spent a mind-boggling 17 percent of the national income on medical care in 1997. No other country in the world approaches that level of spending as a fraction of national income, no matter how its medical care is organized.

Enactment of Medicare and Medicaid provided a direct subsidy for medical care. The cost grew much more rapidly than originally estimated—as the cost of any handout invariably does. Legislation cannot repeal the nonlegislated law of demand and supply: the lower the price, the greater the quantity demanded; at a zero price, the quantity demanded becomes infinite. Some method of rationing must be substituted for price, which invariably means administrative rationing.

A look at the data is instructive. The effect of tax exemption and the enactment of Medicare and Medicaid on rising medical costs from 1946 to now is clear. According to my estimates, the two together accounted for nearly 60 percent of the total increase in cost. Tax exemption alone accounted for one-third of the increase in cost; Medicare and Medicaid, one-quarter.

Now consider a different breakdown of the cost of medical care: between the part paid directly by the government and the part paid privately. Government’s share went from an eighth of the total in 1919 to a quarter in 1965 to nearly half in 1997. The rise in the government’s share has been accompanied by centralization of spending—away from state and local governments to the federal government. We are headed toward completely socialized medicine and are already halfway there, if, in addition to direct costs, we include indirect tax subsidies.

Expressed as a fraction of national income, spending on medical care went from 3 percent of the national income in 1919 to 4.5 percent in 1946 to 7 percent in 1965 to a mind-boggling 17 percent in 1997. No other country in the world approaches that level of spending as a fraction of national income no matter how its medical care is organized. The changing role of medical care in the U.S. economy is truly breathtaking. To illustrate, in 1946, seven times as much was spent on food, beverages, and tobacco as on medical care; in 1996, 50 years later, more was spent on medical care than on food, beverages, and tobacco.

The Changing Meaning of Insurance

Employer financing of medical care has caused the term insurance to acquire a rather different meaning in medicine than in most other contexts. We generally rely on insurance to protect us against events that are highly unlikely to occur but that involve large losses if they do occur—major catastrophes, not minor, regularly recurring expenses. We insure our houses against loss from fire, not against the cost of having to cut the lawn. We insure our cars against liability to others or major damage, not against having to pay for gasoline. Yet in medicine, it has become common to rely on insurance to pay for regular medical examinations and often for prescriptions.

This is partly a question of the size of the deductible and the copayment, but it goes beyond that. "Without medical insurance" and "without access to medical care" have come to be treated as nearly synonymous. Moreover, the states and the federal government have increasingly specified the coverage of insurance for medical care to a detail not common in other areas. The effect has been to raise the cost of insurance and to limit the options open to individuals. Many, if not most, of the "medically uninsured" are persons who for one reason or another do not have access to employer-provided medical care and are unable or unwilling to pay the cost of the only kinds of insurance contracts available to them.

If the tax exemption for employer-provided medical care and Medicare and Medicaid had never been enacted, the insurance market for medical care would probably have developed as other insurance markets have. The typical form of medical insurance would have been catastrophic insurance (i.e., insurance with a very high deductible).

The Black Hole of Bureaucratization

Third-party payment has required the bureaucratization of medical care and, in the process, has changed the character of the relation between physicians (or other caregivers) and patients. A medical transaction is not simply between a caregiver and a patient; it has to be approved as "covered" by a bureaucrat and the appropriate payment authorized. The patient—the recipient of the medical care—has little or no incentive to be concerned about the cost since it’s somebody else’s money. The caregiver has become, in effect, an employee of the insurance company or, in the case of Medicare and Medicaid, of the government. The patient is no longer the one, and the only one, the caregiver has to serve. An inescapable result is that the interest of the patient is often in direct conflict with the interest of the caregiver’s ultimate employer. That has been manifest in public dissatisfaction with the increasingly impersonal character of medical care.

Some years ago, the British physician Max Gammon, after an extensive study of the British system of socialized medicine, formulated what he called "the theory of bureaucratic displacement." He observed that in "a bureaucratic system . . . increase in expenditure will be matched by fall in production. . . . Such systems will act rather like ‘black holes,’ in the economic universe, simultaneously sucking in resources, and shrinking in terms of ‘emitted production.’" Gammon’s observations for the British system have their exact parallel in the partly socialized U.S. medical system. Here, too, input has been going up sharply relative to output. This tendency can be documented particularly clearly for hospitals, thanks to the availability of high-quality data for a long period.

The data document a drastic decline in output over the past half century. From 1946 to 1996, the number of beds per 1,000 population fell by more than 60 percent; the fraction of beds occupied, by more than 20 percent. In sharp contrast, input skyrocketed. Hospital personnel per occupied bed multiplied ninefold, and cost per patient day, adjusted for inflation, an astounding fortyfold, from $30 in 1946 to $1,200 in 1996. A major engine of these changes was the enactment of Medicare and Medicaid in 1965. A mild rise in input was turned into a meteoric rise; a mild fall in output, into a rapid decline. Hospital days per person per year were cut by two-thirds, from three days in 1946 to an average of less than a day by 1996.

Taken by itself, the decline in hospital days is evidence of progress in medical science. A healthy population needs less hospitalization, and advances in science and medical technology have reduced the length of hospital stays and increased outpatient surgery. Progress in medical science may well explain most of the decline in output; it does not explain much, if any, of the rise in input per unit of output. True, medical machines have become more complex. However, in other areas where there has been great technical progress—whether it be agriculture or telephones or steel or automobiles or aviation or, most recently,computers and the Internet—progress has led to a reduc- tion, not an increase, in cost per unit of output. Why is medicine an exception? Gammon’s law, not medical miracles, was clearly at work. The provision of medical care as an untaxed fringe benefit by employers, and then the federal government’s assumption of responsibility for hospital and medical care of the elderly and the poor, provided a fresh pool of money. And there was no shortage of takers. Growing costs, in turn, led to more regulation of hospitals and medical care, further increasing administrative costs and leading to the bureaucratization that is so prominent a feature of medical care today.

So much for input. What about output? What have we gotten in return for quadrupling the share of the nation’s income spent on medical care?

I have already referred to one component of output—days of hospital care per person per year. That has gone down from three days in 1946 to less than one in 1996. Insofar as the reduction reflects the improvements in medicine, it clearly is a good thing. However, it also reflects the pressure to keep hospital stays short in order to keep down cost. That this is not a good thing is clear from protests by patients, widespread enough to have led Congress to mandate minimum stays for some medical procedures.

The output of the medical care industry that we are interested in is its contribution to better health. How can we measure better health in a reasonably objective way that is not greatly influenced by other factors?

The least bad measure that I have been able to come up with is length of life, though that too is seriously contaminated by other factors—improvements in diet, housing, clothing, and so on generated by greater affluence, better garbage collection and disposal, the provision of purer water, and other governmental public health measures.

Expected longevity went from 47 years in 1900 to 68 years in 1950, a truly remarkable rise. From 1950 on, expected longevity continued to increase but at a much slower rate, reaching 76 years in 1997. For our purposes, it is of fundamental importance that, whatever its source, the increase in longevity did not have any systematic relation to spending on medical care as a fraction of income.

On the evidence to date, it is hard to see that we have gotten much for quadrupling the share of the nation’s income spent on medical care other than bureaucratization and widespread dissatisfaction with the economic organization of medical care.

The United States versus Other Countries

Our steady movement toward reliance on third-party payment no doubt explains the extraordinary rise in spending on medical care in the United States. However, other advanced countries also rely on third-party payment, many or most of them to an even greater extent than we do. What explains our higher level of spending?

I must confess that despite much thought and scouring of the literature, I have no satisfactory answer. One clue is my estimate that if the pre–World War II system had continued—that is, if tax exemption and Medicare and Medicaid had never been enacted—expenditures on medical care would have amounted to less than half the current level, which would have put us near the bottom of the OECD list rather than at the top.

In terms of holding down cost, one-payer directly administered government systems, such as exist in Canada and Great Britain, have a real advantage over our mixed system. As the direct purchaser of all or nearly all medical services, they are in a monopoly position in hiring physicians and can hold down their remuneration, so that physicians earn much less in those countries than in the United States. In addition, they can ration care more directly—at the cost of long waiting lists and much dissatisfaction.

In addition, once the whole population is covered, there is little political incentive to increase spending on medical care. Once the bulk of costs have been taken over by government, as they have in most of the other OECD countries, the politician does not have the carrot of increased services with which to attract new voters, so attention turns to holding down costs.

An additional factor is the tax treatment of private expenditures on medical care. In most countries, any private expenditure comes out of after-tax income. It does in the United States also, unless the medical care is provided by the employer. For this reason, the bulk of medical care is provided through employers, and private expenditures on medical care are decidedly higher than they would be if medical care, like food, clothing, and other consumer goods, had to be financed out of posttax income. It is consistent with this view that Germany, the country second to the United States in the fraction of income spent on medical care, has a system in which the employer plays a central role in the provision of medical care and in which, so far as I have been able to determine, half of the cost comes out of pretax income and half out of posttax income.

Our mixed system has many advantages in accessibility and quality of medical care, but it has produced a higher level of cost than would result from either wholly individual choice or wholly collective choice.

Conclusion: Medical Savings Accounts and Beyond

The high cost and inequitable character of our medical care system are the direct result of our steady movement toward reliance on third-party payment. A cure requires reversing course, reprivatizing medical care by eliminating most third-party payment, and restoring the role of insurance to providing protection against major medical catastrophes.

The ideal way to do that would be to reverse past actions: repeal the tax exemption of employer-provided medical care; terminate Medicare and Medicaid; deregulate most insurance; and restrict the role of the government, preferably state and local rather than federal, to financing care for the hard cases. However, the vested interests that have grown up around the existing system, and the tyranny of the status quo, clearly make that solution not feasible politically. Yet it is worth stating the ideal as a guide to judging whether proposed incremental changes are in the right direction.

Most changes made in the final decade of the twentieth century were in the wrong direction. Despite rejection of the sweeping socialization of medicine proposed by Hillary Clinton, subsequent incremental changes have expanded the role of government, increased regulation of medical practice, and further constrained the terms of medical insurance, thereby raising its cost and increasing the fraction of individuals who choose or are forced to go without insurance.

There is one exception, which, though minor in current scope, is pregnant of future possibilities. The Kassebaum-Kennedy Bill, passed in 1996 after lengthy and acrimonious debate, included a narrowly limited four-year pilot program authorizing medical savings accounts. A medical savings account enables individuals to deposit tax-free funds in an account usable only for medical expense, provided they have a high-deductible insurance policy that limits the maximum out-of-pocket expense. As noted earlier, it eliminates third-party payment except for major medical expenses and is thus a movement very much in the right direction. By extending tax exemption to all medical expenses whether paid by the employer or not, it eliminates the present bias in favor of employer-provided medical care. That too is a move in the right direction. However, the extension of tax exemption increases the bias in favor of medical care compared to other household expenditures. This effect would tend to increase the implicit government subsidy for medical care, which would be a step in the wrong direction.

Before this pilot project, a number of large companies (e.g., Quaker Oats, Forbes, Golden Rule Insurance Company) had offered their employees the choice of a medical savings account instead of the usual low-deductible employer-provided insurance policy. In each case, the employer purchased a high-deductible major medical insurance policy for the employee and deposited a stated sum, generally about half of the deductible, in a medical savings account for the employee. That sum could be used by the employee for medical care. Any part not used during the year was the property of the employee and had to be included in taxable income. Despite the loss of the tax exemption, this alternative has generally been very popular with both employers and employees. It has reduced costs for the employer and empowered the employee, eliminating much third-party payment.

Medical savings accounts offer one way to resolve the growing financial and administrative problems of Medicare and Medicaid. It seems clear from private experience that a program along these lines would be less expensive and bureaucratic than the current system and more satisfactory to the participants. In effect, it would be a way to voucherize Medicare and Medicaid. It would enable participants to spend their own money on themselves for routine medical care and medical problems, rather than having to go through HMOs and insurance companies, while at the same time providing protection against medical catastrophes.

A more radical reform would, first, end both Medicare and Medicaid, at least for new entrants, and replace them by providing every family in the United States with catastrophic insurance (i.e., a major medical policy with a high deductible). Second, it would end tax exemption of employer-provided medical care. And, third, it would remove the restrictive regulations that are now imposed on medical insurance—hard to justify with universal catastrophic insurance.

This reform would solve the problem of the currently medically uninsured, eliminate most of the bureaucratic structure, free medical practitioners from an increasingly heavy burden of paperwork and regulation, and lead many employers and employees to convert employer-provided medical care into a higher cash wage. The taxpayer would save money because total government costs would plummet. The family would be relieved of one of its major concerns—the possibility of being impoverished by a major medical catastrophe—and most could readily finance the remaining medical costs. Families would once again have an incentive to monitor the providers of medical care and to establish the kind of personal relations with them that were once customary. The demonstrated efficiency of private enterprise would have a chance to improve the quality and lower the cost of medical care. The first question asked of a patient entering a hospital might once again become "What’s wrong?" not "What’s your insurance?"


A longer version of this essay appeared in Public Interest, winter 2001.

Available from the Hoover Press is To America’s Health: A Proposal to Reform the Food and Drug Administration, by Henry I. Miller. Also available is The Essence of Friedman, edited by Kurt R. Leube. To order, call 800-935-2882.



TOPICS: Business/Economy; Canada; Culture/Society; Editorial; Foreign Affairs; Germany; Government; Japan; News/Current Events; United Kingdom
KEYWORDS: healthcare; miltonfriedman; msa; socializedmedicine
Navigation: use the links below to view more comments.
first previous 1-2021-4041-50 last
To: Black Birch
What are the figures that are being bounced around other than the drug savings?

First year little savings. After that, it is up to the frugality of the employees to lower the costs.

41 posted on 03/06/2005 5:29:03 PM PST by Erik Latranyi (9-11 is your Peace Dividend)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 40 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Marten
One thing that he failed to mention is that insurance companies have a vested interest in keeping medical expenses high. If they were to fight to lower expenses fewer people would need insurance (because they could pay for it on their own).

Fear is a great motivator for insurance and the insurance companies know it and try to ratchet up the costs to increase the fear.

The other problem is that the medical profession is virtually a monopoly. Most of what doctors do is prescribe pills and it generally doesn't take a medical degree to figure out the right pill for the ailment. Why should it be illegal for me to give myself a tetanus or penicillin shot and legal for diabetics to inject insulin?
42 posted on 03/06/2005 6:22:28 PM PST by LeGrande
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Marten
All insurance systems are socialized -- they are inherently designed to spread cost over membership. The only difference between private and national socialized insurance is that the one is voluntary (sort of, as M.F. points out, via tax incentives and disincentives), and the other compulsory. And the only difference in profit between private and national insurance is that the one goes into the insurer's coffers and the other to the taxman's.

Insurance may be a necessary evil, but it should only be for catastrophic circumstances, rather than for everyday costs. Otherwise, as is now, it's like Midas, and makes everything it touches as expensive as gold.



Nicollo unmasked: Bromleyisms here

43 posted on 03/06/2005 6:30:17 PM PST by nicollo
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Marten

My family is the type that pays out a lot more out in medical insurance than we ever get back. Which is fair to a point, since the insurance company is assuming my risk. We only go to the doctor once or twice a year, if that.

Anyway, I went to the ER on Christmas Day because I'd cut my finger bad enough to need stitches. Insurance covered most of the costs, no problem.

Last week I got a letter from my insurer demanding (yes, demanding) that I fill out a questionnaire. The questions weren't about the quality of the care I received - they wanted to make sure I wasn't going to collect any other insurance, or sue anybody and not give them a cut.

The most telling was a statement: "Do not ignore this obligation to your insurance company". Gosh, and here I though that I was the customer and my insurance company had obligations to me.

These outfits know that urgent care is beyond the means of most people, and treat them accordingly. We're not customers anymore, we're cattle and are accorded like treatment.

We need medical savings accounts NOW.


44 posted on 03/06/2005 7:11:16 PM PST by Doohickey ("This is a hard and dirty war, but when it's over, nothing will ever be too difficult again.”)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Marten

A very worthwhile essay. Thanks for posting it again.


45 posted on 03/06/2005 7:15:15 PM PST by Sam Cree (Democrats are herd animals)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Marten

I've got an idea.. we could further restrict the number of doctors allowed to train.

Also what other profession do you guys know where you need a doctorate to do routine jobs? Can you imagine if every car that was built, had to be specially designed by a doctorate of engineering? And the number of those doctorates was restricted by the state.

Can you imagine what cars would cost? Only the rich could afford them.. and those doctorates would live a privaleged life indeed...

Welcome to health care in America.


46 posted on 03/06/2005 7:22:21 PM PST by ran15
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: LeGrande
The other problem is that the medical profession is virtually a monopoly. Most of what doctors do is prescribe pills and it generally doesn't take a medical degree to figure out the right pill for the ailment. Why should it be illegal for me to give myself a tetanus or penicillin shot and legal for diabetics to inject insulin?

Excellent question.

Medical care is expensive because the supply of health care professionals is insufficient to meet the demand. The supply of doctors is kept artificially low by the AMA's monopoly on accreditation of med schools and the restrictiveness of state licensing boards. In addition to this comes the high cost of medical education, which forces doctors into debt early, and the overhead costs of record keeping, admin, and malpractice insurance.

The fact is that most people do not need the services of a licensed M.D. for everyday sneeze & sniffle care. For everyday care of healthy adults and children the expertise of an RN and a PA are more than sufficient. Therefore, the federal government should take steps to force state licensure boards to allow RNs, PAs, and EMTs greater latitude in practice. Allowing these providers to prescribe drugs, perform basic exams, treat common illnesses, and provide general care on a strict cash-and-carry basis in a clinical setting would dramatically lower costs. Why pay $200/hour for the services of an M.D. when you really only need the $50/hour services of an RN? In my scenario, these health care service providers would be based in neighborhood clinics which would be the ordinary person's most frequent point of contact with the medical profession. There, the RNs and PAs would provide outpatient care for everyday ailments, with a team of EMTs on call for ER support and a licensed M.D. supervisor on call at the local hospital to handle more serious cases (broken bones, infectious disease, surgery, etc.) Such clinics would replace the local ER as the primary health care provider for the average person. The state government could fund and administer a malpractice insurance pool to protect the providers. Since the overhead would be low and the treatment limited to routine care, costs would be far lower than those of a huge hospital or a multi-doctor practice. With no insurance papers to file, these clinics would furthermore have no need for admin staff, thus further lower costs.

The high cost of medical education is another barrier to inexpensive health care. The solution is to increase the number of medical schools by breaking the AMA's grip on accreditation. Another is to create a national health care education system at the federal level to allow those unable to pay for med school to become doctors. My idea would work like this: Congress would create and fund the United States Medical Service Corps as a division of the Public Health Service. This Corps would operate a United States Medical Academy -- a uniformed service academy similar to Annapolis or West Point -- to which talented high school students could apply. If accepted, the students would become cadets at the academy for four years, at which time they would receive a Bachelor of Science degree and a commission as Health Service Officers in the Public Health Service. From there, the Health Service Officers would proceed to a four-year term of service with the PHS, either as students (in medical school), as RNs, PAs, or EMTs in residency at various federal health care facilities. These officers would train and serve internships wherever needed for those four years while earning the same pay as their military grade counterparts. At the end of four years of service, the officers (now fully-licensed MDs, RNs, or PAs, or EMTs) would be free to reenlist and continue to serve in the PHS or leave the service and begin private practice free of debt. In other words, the government would train and educate hundreds of doctors, nurses, and other health care professionals free of charge in exchange for at least four years of public service. This, I think, would be an effective use of taxpayer dollars.

Indigent care is our most serious health care problem. Friedman does not address how MSAs would solve the problem created by the vast numbers of illegal immigrants with no insurance and no money in this country who have turned our county hospital ERs into basic healthcre providers. My solution to this problem would be a voucher system funded by the state; any legal resident or citizen below the poverty line would be issued a Health Service Card. This swipe card would be "charged" with a certain amount of money every year and would be honored by any health care provider. This would allow indigent patients to use their neighborhood clinics for routine care instead of swamping the ER at County General as they do now. By using a swipe card, the need for admin staff would be near nil; the transaction would be 100% digital. For this system to work, we would of course need to institute a system of national citizen/legal resident ID -- which is one more reason to have such a system. Those persons with no legal right to be here would not receive a state health card; instead, they would be detained by Immigration police, transported to a Federal facility for treatment, and eventually deported.

Health care cannot be treated on a strict commodity basis; the risk of infectious disease is too great to allow people with no money to go without medical care. Besides, people with no cash or insurance are not simply going to squat on a toadstool and quietly watch their children suffer and die when a big, shiny hospital is sitting down the block. By allowing more people (RNs, PAs, and perhaps pharmacists) to provide everyday health care and advice, we can increase supply relative to demand and slash health care costs. By creating a Federal medical service, we can offer poor but talented youths an opportunity to gain a medical education in exchange for their service to the nation. And by establishing state-run risk pools for malpractice insurance and by instituting a digital voucher system for indigent care, we can further control the cost of providing basic health care, and free our public hospitals of the burden of providing basic care for indigents and/or illegal aliens, while making sure that health care services are available to all regardless of ability to pay.

47 posted on 03/06/2005 8:11:23 PM PST by B-Chan (Catholic. Monarchist. Texan. Any questions?)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 42 | View Replies]

To: B-Chan
I heartily agree with your solution except that I don't think that the government needs to create a Medical Corp. Letting Nurses, EMT's and responsible people write prescriptions and treat minor medical problems would probably solve the shortage all by itself.

I am curious. Does anyone know the top ten reasons people go to the doctor? My guess is that is for trivial stuff that any competent nurse could handle
48 posted on 03/06/2005 8:46:17 PM PST by LeGrande
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 47 | View Replies]

To: LeGrande

You are dead on my friend. Can you imagine if you took your car to the mechanics shop.. but had to see someone with a 10 year doctorate in mechanical engineering to diagnose it, and order the say new tire?

I bookmarked a study that looked at how much money could be saved, without sacrficing any care by letting experienced nurses deal with the simple problems..

Most professions you have people with a few years training dealing with the routine problems. Then when that doesn't solve the problem it goes to the next level.. the 4 year degree holders. Then in the rare case that still doesn't solve it, it goes to a research doctorate.

I know in electrical engineering, the technicians can handle 97% of the issues...

Being VERY conservative the study on nursing found they could handle 80% of the issues, at 40% of the cost. While getting rid of waiting times.

Guess who came out against that study?


49 posted on 03/06/2005 9:42:54 PM PST by ran15
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 48 | View Replies]

To: Bitwhacker

I agree with you that Friedman DID ignore half of the problem of huge increases, but I suspect that he relies on the consumer to rethink the cost of defensive medicine if they were paying the bills themselves, and that doctors would be able to demand from the patient a release if they weren't willing to undergo such a procedure after being properly advised.


50 posted on 03/06/2005 10:38:19 PM PST by AFPhys ((.Praying for President Bush, our troops, their families, and all my American neighbors..))
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 33 | View Replies]


Navigation: use the links below to view more comments.
first previous 1-2021-4041-50 last

Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.

Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

FreeRepublic, LLC, PO BOX 9771, FRESNO, CA 93794
FreeRepublic.com is powered by software copyright 2000-2008 John Robinson