Posted on 06/06/2025 8:35:06 AM PDT by SeekAndFind
Today my latest book, How Countries Go Broke: The Big Cycle , is being released. This note is to share what it says in a nutshell. To me, what matters most is conveying understanding at this critically important moment, so I want to pass the key ideas in extreme brevity in this note, as well as comprehensively in the book, and leave it to you decide how deep you want to go.
I have been a global macro investor for over 50 years, have bet on government debt markets for nearly as long, and have done very well doing that. While I previously kept to myself my understanding of the mechanics of how big debt crises transpire and the principles I use to navigate them, I'm now at the stage of life where I want to pass these understandings along to help people. This is especially true now as I see the U.S. and other countries headed toward having the equivalent of economic heart attacks. That led me to write How Countries Go Broke: The Big Cycle , which comprehensively explains the mechanics and principles I use, and this very brief summary of the book.
The debt dynamics work the same for a government as they do for a person or a company, except that the central government has a central bank that can print money (which devalues it) and it can take money away from people via taxes. For these reasons, if you can imagine how the debt dynamics would work for you or a business you run if you could print money or get money from people by taxing them, you can understand the dynamic. But keep in mind that your goal is to make the overall system run well, not just for yourself, but for all citizens.
To me, the credit/market system is like the circulatory system, bringing nutrients to all parts of the body that make up our markets and economy. If credit is used effectively, it creates productivity and income that can pay back the debt and interest on the debt, which is healthy. However, if it isn't used well so it doesn't produce enough income to pay back the debt and the interest on the debt, debt service will build up like plaque that squeezes out other spending. When debt service payments become very large, that creates a debt service problem and eventually a debt rollover problem as holders of the debt don't want to roll it over and want to sell it. Naturally that creates a shortage of demand for debt instruments like bonds and the selling of them, and naturally when there is a shortage of demand relative to supply that either leads to a) interest rates rising, which drives markets and the economy lower, or b) the central banks "printing money" and buying debt which lowers the value of money which raises inflation from what it would have been. Printing money also artificially lowers interest rates, which hurts the lenders’ returns. Neither approach is good. When interest rates rise because the selling of debt becomes too large to curtail and the central bank has bought a lot of bonds, the central bank loses money, which hurts its cash flow. If this continues, it leads the central bank to having a negative net worth.
When this becomes severe, both the central government and the central bank borrow to make debt service payments, the central bank prints money to provide the lending because the free-market demand is inadequate, and a self-reinforcing debt/money printing/ inflation spiral ensues. In summary, the classic things to watch are as follows:
1) The amount of government debt service there is relative to government revenue (which is like the amount of plaque in the circulatory system),
2) The amount of the selling of government debt there is relative to the amount of demand for government debt (which is like the plaque breaking off and causing a heart attack), and
3) the amount of central banks' governments printing money to purchase government debt to make up the shortfall in demand for government debt relative to the supply of government debt that needs to be sold (which is like the doctor/central bank administering a heavy dose of liquidity/credit to ease the liquidity shortage, producing more debt which the central bank has an exposure to).
These all typically increase in a long-term, multi-decade cycle of rising debt and debt service payments relative to incomes until that can't continue because 1) debt service expenses unacceptably crowd out other spending, 2) the supply of the debt that has to be bought is so large relative to the demand to buy that debt that interest rates have to rise substantially, which sends the markets and the economy down a lot, or 3) rather than allow interest rates to rise and the bad markets/bad economy outcome to happen, the central bank prints a lot of money and buys a lot of government debt to make up for the demand shortfall, which sends the value of money down a lot.
In either case, the bonds have a bad return until the money and the debt eventually become so cheap that they can attract demand and/or the debt can be cheaply bought back or restructured by the government.
That is what the Big Debt Cycle looks like in a tiny nutshell.
Because one can measure these things, one can monitor this debt dynamic happening, so it's easy to see problems approaching. I’ve used this diagnostic process in my investing and I’ve kept it to myself, but I’m now explaining it in detail in How Countries Go Broke: The Big Cycle because now it is too important to keep to myself.
To describe it more specifically, one can see debts and debt service payments rising relative to incomes, the supply of debt being larger than the demand for it and central banks dealing with these things happening by being stimulative at first by cutting short term interest rates and then by printing money and buying debt, and eventually the central bank losing money and then having a negative net worth, and both the central government and taking on more debt to pay the debt service and the central bank monetizing the debt. All these things lead toward a government debt crisis which produces the equivalent of an economic heart attack that comes when the constriction of debt-financed spending shuts down the normal flow of the circulatory system.
Early in the final stage of this big debt cycle, the market action reflects this dynamic via interest rates rising led by long term rates, the currency declining especially relative to gold, and the central government's treasury department shortening the maturities of its debt offerings because of a shortage of the demand for long term debt. Typically, late in the process when this dynamic is most severe, a number of other seemingly extreme measures are put into place like establishing capital controls and exerting extraordinary pressures on creditors to buy and not sell debt. This dynamic is explained much more completely in my book along with lots of charts and numbers to show it happening.
Now, imagine that you are running a big business called the U.S. government. That will give you a perspective that will help you understand the U.S. government’s finances and its leadership’s choices.
The total revenue this year will be about $5 trillion while the total expenses will be about $7 trillion, so there will be a budget shortfall of about $2 trillion. So, this year, your organization’s spending will be about 40 percent more than it is taking in. And there is very little ability to cut expenses because almost all the expenses are previously committed to or are essential expenses. Because your organization borrowed a lot over a long time, it has accumulated a big debt—approximately six times the amount that it is bringing in each year (about $30 trillion), which equals about $230,000 per household that you have to take care of. And the interest bill on the debt will be about $1 trillion which is about 20 percent of your enterprise’s revenue and half this year’s budget shortfall (deficit) that you will have to borrow to fund. But that $1 trillion is not all that you have to give your creditors, because in addition to the interest you have to pay on your debt, you have to have to pay back the principal that is coming due, which is around $9 trillion. You hope that your creditors, or some other rich entities, will either relend or lend it to you or some other rich entities. So, the debt service payments—in other words the paying back of principal and interest that you have to do to not default—is about $10 trillion, which is about 200 percent of the money coming in.
That is the current condition.
So, what is going to happen? Let’s imagine it. You are going to borrow the money to fund the deficit whatever that deficit is going to be. There is a lot of argument about what it’s going to be. Most of the independent assessors of the situation project that the debt in 10 years will be $50-55tn (which will be 6.5-7 times revenue), because there will be $20-25tn of additional borrowing. Of course, in ten years, that will leave this organization with more debt service payments squeezing out spending and more risk that there won’t be enough demand for the debt it has to sell without a plan to deal with this situation.
That’s the picture.
I am confident that the governments’ financial condition is at an inflection point because, if this is not dealt with now, the debts will build up to levels where they can’t be managed without great trauma, and it is especially important that this operation happens while the system is relatively strong rather than when it is weak. That is because when the economy is in a contraction, the government’s borrowing needs increase a lot.
From my analysis, I believe that this situation needs to be dealt with via what I call my 3 percent, 3-part solution. That would be to get the budget deficit down to 3 percent of GDP in a way that balances the three ways of reducing the deficit which are 1) cutting spending, 2) increasing tax revenue, and 3) lowering interest rates. All three need to happen concurrently so as to prevent any one from being too large, because if any one is too large, the adjustment will be traumatic. And these things need to come about through good fundamental adjustments rather than be forced (e.g., it would be very bad if the Federal Reserve unnaturally forced interest rates down). Based on my projections, spending cuts and tax revenue increases by about 4% each relative to current planning, and interest rates falling by about 1-1.5% in response, would lead to interest payments that are lower by 1-2% of GDP over the next decade and stimulate a rise in asset prices and economic activity which will bring in much more revenue.
Q1: Why do big government debt crises and big debt cycles happen?
Big government debt crises and big debt cycles happen and can easily be measured by 1) the amount of government debt service there is relative to government revenue rises to the point that it unacceptably squeezes out essential government spending 2) the amount of selling of government debt there is relative to the amount of demand for government debt becomes too large so interest rates rise causing markets and the economy to decline, and 3) central banks responding to these conditions through lower interest rates which reduces the demand for the bonds which then leads central banks to print money to purchase government debt which devalues the money. These things typically increase in a long-term, multi-decade cycle until they can't continue anymore because 1) debt service expenses unacceptably crowd out other spending, 2) the supply of the debt that has to be bought is so large relative to the demand to buy that debt that interest rates have to rise a lot which sends the markets and the economy down a lot or 3) the central bank prints a lot of money and buys a lot of government debt to make up for the demand shortfall which sends the value of money down a lot. In either case, the bonds have a bad return until they become so cheap that they can attract demand and/or the debt can be restructured. One can easily measure these things and see them moving toward an impending debt crisis. It comes when the constriction of debt-financed spending happens, like a debt-induced economic heart attack.
Throughout history these debt cycles have occurred in virtually every country, typically several times, so there are literally hundreds of historical cases to look at. Said differently, all monetary orders have broken down and the debt cycle process I'm describing is behind these breakdowns. They go back as far as there is recorded history. This is the process that led to the breakdowns of all reserve currencies like the British Pound and the Dutch Guilder before the Pound. In my book, I show the most recent 35 cases.
Q2: If this process happens repeatedly, why are the dynamics behind it not well understood?
You’re right that it’s not well understood. Interestingly, I couldn't find any studies about how this happens. I theorize that it is not well understood because it typically happens only about once a lifetime in reserve currency countries—when their monetary orders break down—and when it happens in non-reserve currency countries, this dynamic is presumed to be a problem that reserve currency countries are immune to. The only reason I discovered this process is that I saw it happening in my sovereign bond market investing, which led me to study many cases of it happening throughout history so I that I could navigate them well (such as navigating the 2008 global financial crisis and the 2010-15 European debt crisis).
Q3: How worried should we really be about a “heart attack” debt crisis in the U.S. when waiting for U.S. debt issues to blow up. People have heard a lot about the pending debt crisis that never came? What makes this time different?
I think we should be very worried because of the previously mentioned conditions. I think that those who worried about the debt crisis happening before, when conditions were less severe, were right to worry about it then because addressing it earlier could have prevented the conditions from getting so bad, like warning against smoking and eating poorly early. So, I theorize that the reason this issue isn’t more widely worried about is both because it isn’t well enough understood and because there is a lot of complacency that has developed as a result of the premature warnings. It’s like someone with a lot of plaque in their arteries who is eating a lot of fatty food and not exercising saying to his doctor, “You’ve warned me that bad things would happen to me if I didn’t change my ways, but I haven’t had a heart attack yet. Why should I believe you now?”
Q4: What could be the catalyst for a U.S. debt crisis today, when will it happen, and what would such a crisis look like?
The catalysts will be a convergence of the previously mentioned influences. As for the timing, it can be hastened or postponed by policies and exogenous factors, like big political shifts and wars. For example, if the budget deficit is lowered to about 3 percent of GDP from what I and most others project to be about 7 percent of GDP, that would reduce the risks a lot. If there are exogenous big shocks, it will come earlier, and if there aren’t, it will come later or not at all (if it is managed well). My guess, which I suppose will be a bad one, is that it will come in three years, give or take two, if the course we’re on is not changed.
Q5: Do you know of any analogous cases of the budget deficit being cut so much in the way you describe and good outcomes happening?
Yes. I know of several. My plan would lead to a cut in the budget deficit of about four percent of GDP. The most analogous case of that happening with a good outcome was in the United States from 1991 to 1998 when the budget deficit was cut by five percent of GDP. In my book, I list several similar cases that happened in several countries.
Q6: Some people have argued that the U.S. is generally less vulnerable to debt-related problems/crises because of the dominant role of the dollar in the global economy. What do you believe those who make that argument are missing/under-appreciating?
If they believe this, they are missing an understanding of the mechanics and the lessons of history. More specifically, they should be examining history to understand why all prior reserve currencies ended being reserve currencies. Stated very simply, currency and debt have to be effective storeholds of wealth or they will be devalued and abandoned. The dynamic I am describing explains how a reserve currency loses its effectiveness as a storehold of wealth.
Q7: Japan—whose 215% debt-to-GDP ratio is the highest of any advanced economy—has often served as the poster child for the argument that a country can live with consistently high debt levels without experiencing a debt crisis. Why don’t you take much comfort from Japan’s experience?
The Japanese case exemplifies and will continue to exemplify the problem I describe, and it demonstrates in practice my theory. More specifically, because of the high level of the Japanese government’s over-indebtedness, Japanese bonds and debt have been terrible investments. To make up for a shortage of demand for Japanese debt assets at low enough interest rates to be good for the country, the BoJ printed a lot of money and bought a lot of Japanese government debt which led to holders of Japanese bonds having losses of 45% relative to holding US dollar debt since 2013 and losses of 60% relative to holding gold since 2013. The typical wages of a Japanese worker have fallen 58% since 2013 in common currency terms relative to the wages of an American worker. I have a whole chapter on the Japanese case in my book that explains it in depth.
Q8: Are there any other areas of the world that look particularly problematic from a fiscal standpoint that people may be underappreciating?
Most countries have similar debt and deficit problems. The UK, EU, China, and Japan all do. That is why I expect a similar debt and currency devaluation adjustment process in most countries, which is why I expect non-government produced monies like gold and bitcoin to do relatively well.
Q9: How should investors navigate this risk/be positioned going forward?
Everyone’s financial situation is different, but as general advice, I suggest diversifying well in asset classes and countries that have strong income statements and balance sheets and are not having great internal political and external geopolitical conflicts, underweighting debt assets like bonds, and overweighting gold and a bit of bitcoin. Having a small percentage of one’s money in gold can reduce the portfolio’s risk, and I think it will also raise its return.
The views expressed here are my own and not necessarily those of Bridgewater.
Click here: to donate by Credit Card
Or here: to donate by PayPal
Or by mail to: Free Republic, LLC - PO Box 9771 - Fresno, CA 93794
Thank you very much and God bless you.
Traitorous CIA clown.
.
Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.