Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

Skip to comments.

Not Enough Money
National Review ^ | April 6, 2011 | Ramesh Ponnuru

Posted on 04/06/2011 8:10:15 AM PDT by Toddsterpatriot

‘To economists reading this essay in 2010, perhaps the most remarkable single fact to note about monetary policy at the end of the interwar period” — the author, Columbia University economist Charles Calomiris, is of course also talking about the end of the Great Depression — “is that its architects were, for the most part, quite pleased with themselves. Far from learning about the errors of their ways during the interwar period, Fed officials congratulated themselves on having adhered to appropriate principles, and to the extent that they were self-critical, it was because they thought that they had been too expansionary.”

Almost all economists today agree that monetary policy during the Depression, especially its early stages, was disastrously tight, indeed that this contractionary policy is the principal reason the Depression became Great. But perhaps we should not judge the central bankers of America in the 1930s too harshly. For one thing, as Calomiris notes, smart economists are still arguing about the precise nature of the Fed’s policy mistakes. He himself presents evidence against the received view that the Federal Reserve precipitated the “recession within a recession” of 1937 by raising banks’ reserve requirements and thus discouraging lending.

More important — and more disturbing — is that it is not at all clear that we have learned from the mistakes of the 1930s. Those central bankers believed that money was easy because interest rates were low and the monetary base (the supply of money under the Fed’s control) had expanded. They worried that further easing would reduce confidence in the dollar. British economist R. G. Hawtrey, writing in the late 1930s, described the climate of opinion in his country at the start of the decade: “Fantastic fears of inflation were expressed. That was to cry ‘Fire! Fire!’ in Noah’s Flood.” The economy was actually deflating, not inflating. Under the influence of the “real-bills doctrine,” some central bankers believed that the money supply should respond only to traders’ need for credit. Anything else would only fuel speculative excess.

Today’s inflation hawks employ the same reasoning that those firefighters did. And they are not wholly wrong. Easier money can lead to a destabilizing run on the currency. Inflation can be associated with low real interest rates and an expanded monetary base. But not always: Not in the 1930s, and almost certainly not today, either. The late Milton Friedman, perhaps the most famous inflation hawk of his generation, spotted the fallacy in his analysis of 1990s Japan: Low interest rates can also be a symptom of an excessively tight monetary policy that has choked off opportunities for growth. A looser policy, by increasing expectations of future economic growth, could actually raise real interest rates.

To see why changes in the monetary base are also an unreliable guide to whether money is loose or tight, I’m afraid it’s necessary to look at an equation. Friedman and others familiarized us with the equation of exchange: MV=PY. What that means is that the money supply (M) times the speed with which money changes hands (V, for velocity) must equal the price level (P) times the size of the real economy (Y). If velocity holds constant and the money supply goes up, either prices must go up or the economy must expand or both.

If, on the other hand, velocity drops — if people have an increased desire to hold money balances — then either prices must drop or the economy must shrink or both. And prices, especially wages, are sticky. They won’t automatically and evenly fall in response to a shock. So at least some of the reduction in PY, and maybe a lot of it, will have to come from real economic contraction. What this suggests is that if velocity drops unexpectedly, stabilizing the economy will require increasing the money supply to make up for it. Another way of putting it is that if the demand for money balances increases, the money supply has to grow to accommodate it. If the Fed does not increase the money supply, its inaction in the face of changing economic conditions amounts to passive tightening.

The money supply is itself the product of the monetary base (B) and the “money multiplier” (m), which measures how changes in the base are being converted into changes in commonly used monetary assets such as checking and money-market accounts. So — I promise this is the last equation — BmV=PY. David Beckworth, a conservative economics professor at Texas State University who maintains a blog, has shown that at the height of the financial crisis in late 2008, velocity dropped significantly and the money multiplier fell off a cliff. The monetary base grew a lot too: The inflation hawks are right about that. But it grew enough to offset only the fall in the money multiplier. It didn’t offset the fall in velocity.

Beckworth’s interpretation: The Fed was increasing the base to save the financial system, not the economy overall. At the same time the Fed was injecting money into the financial system, it instituted a policy of paying banks interest on their reserves — a policy that made them less likely to lend out those reserves (and thus kept m down). That policy helped the banks’ solvency but not the economy. The financial system would almost certainly have benefited more from a broader policy: A rising tide lifts all banks. Both m and V remain well below their pre-crisis levels. Beckworth is among those economists who argue that Fed policy should aim to stabilize the growth of nominal spending — roughly, the total value of the economy in current dollars, which is equal to PY (and therefore to MV and BmV). That policy is superior to trying to grow the base at a steady rate, a much-discussed idea in the past, because it allows the base to change in response to changes in the money multiplier and velocity. It is superior to trying to hold inflation constant because it allows the price level to respond to changes in productivity. It would create a stable environment in which economic actors could make their decisions and contracts.

Josh Hendrickson — an economist at the University of Toledo, and like Beckworth a right-leaning blogger — has shown that the Fed did a pretty good job of stabilizing the growth of nominal income at roughly 5 percent per year during the “great moderation” that lasted from the mid-1980s until the current recession. (Although Beckworth notes that growth was slightly above trend during the housing boom, for which he faults the Fed.) Most debts — notably, most mortgage debts — are contracted in nominal terms, with no inflation adjustment. If people are used to 5 percent growth in nominal incomes each year and make their arrangements accordingly, then an unexpected drop will make their debt burdens heavier and also make them reluctant to make plans for a suddenly uncertain future.

That’s what happened during the recent crisis. Scott Sumner — yet another right-of-center econoblogger, this one based at Bentley University — often notes that in late 2008 and early 2009, we saw the sharpest fall in nominal income since 1938. In his view, much of what we think we know about the recession of 2007–09 is wrong. Not only has money not been loose since the crisis began, but tight money is the fundamental reason the recession was so severe and the recovery has been so halting. He argues that it was more fundamental than the housing bust, since residential-construction employment started falling long before the crisis hit.

An alternative theory of the crisis goes something like this: While a recession may have been inevitable, it was the Fed’s passive tightening that made it a disaster. The recession began in late 2007, although many observers knew it only after the fact. The Fed passively tightened mildly in mid-2008. In the fall of 2008, the financial crisis caused velocity (and the money multiplier) to drop dramatically — in part, perhaps, because political and financial leaders were scaring everyone. The Fed did not act aggressively enough to accommodate the increased demand for money balances, and what had been a mild recession became a severe one.

As panic subsided, velocity stopped falling, and the economy then began to recover. But in mid-2010, the eurozone crisis resulted in a flight to the dollar. Increased demand for dollars again had a contractionary effect, and the Fed took months to respond to it. Finally, in the late summer, it began letting it be known that it would dramatically increase the money supply — an initiative called quantitative easing, or QE2, the first QE having been the injection of money into the financial system in late 2008 — and then, in the fall, it followed through.

A number of justifications were offered for QE2. The most plausible was that if people expected it to move nominal income to a permanently higher path, asset values would increase to reflect this higher expected income stream. Both consumers and investors would then spend more money. The demand for money, in other words, would decline at the same time as the supply increased, restoring equilibrium.

As the market became convinced that the Fed planned to act, both expectations of inflation and expectations of real growth increased: the former indicated in the spreads between inflation-indexed bonds and non-indexed bonds, the latter in real interest rates. Nominal income thus moved closer to trend, if not as much as it would have with a bolder Fed initiative. (An explicit announcement that the Fed is willing to do what it takes to restore the trend might itself change expectations enough to make great exertions by it unnecessary.) Stocks picked up too. QE2, though flawed, worked. It began to work even before being formally implemented.

Conservative politicians and conservative pundits nonetheless blasted it. They seized on the rise in long-term interest rates as proof it was not stimulating the economy: the precise kind of confusion about the meaning of interest-rate changes that Friedman had warned against. They blamed QE2 for a boom in commodities prices, largely ignoring the role of rising Asian demand for those commodities. And they fretted about runaway inflation, even though, in the aftermath of QE2, the spreads mentioned above were forecasting inflation rates below 2 percent for years to come — a lower average inflation rate than in each of the last five decades. The argument for stabilizing the growth of nominal income implies that if the Fed overshoots its target in one year it should undershoot it the next, and vice versa: The key is to keep to the targeted long-term trend. Any rational person would want as much of the growth in nominal income to be made up of real economic gains, and as little of it of inflation, as possible. But a modest uptick in inflation that helps to bring nominal income back to trend is better than staying below trend.

There is a reasonable argument — made by Beckworth, among others — that over time the Fed should gradually reduce the average growth of nominal income from 5 percent per year to something closer to 3 percent. The idea would be to move the economy to a lower average inflation rate, or even to a mild and gradual deflation. But such a move should neither be abrupt nor begin in the midst of a shaky recovery, let alone a crisis.

In warning about inflation, conservatives are crying “fire” in, if not Noah’s flood, at least a torrential rain. It may be that they are stuck not so much in the 1930s as in the 1970s — the time when conservatism forged much of its current outlook on economics, and a time when monetary restraint was badly needed. Conservatives also tend to think that loosening monetary policy is a kind of intervention in free markets, and therefore to be suspicious of it. But this is an error. Professor Hendrickson points out that in a system of free banking, with competitive note issue rather than a central bank, the desire for profit and the need for solvency would lead to the supply of banknotes roughly equaling the demand. In a fiat-money regime such as the one under which we, for better or worse, live, a central bank’s withholding of a sufficient supply of money is just as much of an intervention in the economy as its overproduction of it.

The economy, post-QE2, seems to be on the mend. But events overseas — a renewed eurozone crisis, or trouble in the Middle East — could again boost demand for dollars. If so, will the Fed accommodate that demand? Or will it be dissuaded by the vehement criticism its efforts to date have already drawn from conservatives? Congressional Republicans are at the moment blocking the confirmation of Peter Diamond, a Nobel Prize–winning economist, to the Federal Reserve’s board of governors because of their opposition to the inflation they believe is just around the corner.

We are not likely to see a second Great Depression. But it would be tragic if conservatives, moved by hostility to the Fed, led it to repeat, even on a smaller scale, the worst mistakes in its history.

— Ramesh Ponnuru is a senior editor for National Review. This article originally appeared in the April 4, 2011, issue of National Review.


TOPICS: Business/Economy; Government
KEYWORDS:

1 posted on 04/06/2011 8:10:17 AM PDT by Toddsterpatriot
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | View Replies]

To: 1rudeboy; Mase; expat_panama; Rusty0604; Jim 0216; xjcsa; VegasCowboy; 10Ring; Bishop_Malachi

Very long, very interesting.....


2 posted on 04/06/2011 8:11:00 AM PDT by Toddsterpatriot (Math is hard. Harder if you're stupid.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Toddsterpatriot

It’s not the monetary easiing that causes me a problem, it’s the incredible debt and deficit.


3 posted on 04/06/2011 8:25:14 AM PDT by bkepley
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Toddsterpatriot; TigerLikesRooster
Great article. This has got to be one of the best pieces on Macroeconomics that National Review has published in a long time. Thanks for posting.

It serves as a nice antedote to the alarmists who, not understanding monetary economics, see inflation lurking behind every corner.

The discussion of the quantity theory of money (MV=PY) was particularly good.

4 posted on 04/06/2011 8:29:29 AM PDT by curiosity
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Toddsterpatriot

I read this in the dead tree edition last night while on the treadmill at the gym.

Ponnuru found the few potentially conservative academic economists who agree with him that money supply was properly or perhaps even insufficiently juiced by Helicopter Ben during the recession.

Ponnuru goes on to blame the length of the recession on INSUFFICIENT juicing of the money supply.

Not addressed by Ponnuru whatsoever are the following:

1) Inflationary expectations
2) Actual Inflation on the ground today
3) The price of gold, a hedge against inflation
4) The general weakening of the U.S. Dollar against most currencies
5) The possibility that 0bamanomics and 0bamaCare (Fiscal) rather that insufficiently loose monetary policy (Monetary) policy are to blame for the length of the recession
6) That the plain losses incurred by lenders have not been allowed to be recognized on their balance sheets and income statements; rather, the government is supporting zombie banks with easy money

And I could think of a few more with time.

The article seems like a half-informed Econ undergrad writing an apologia for 0bama.

I’m not happy with National Review’s sturdiness in monetary policy.


5 posted on 04/06/2011 8:31:55 AM PDT by Uncle Miltie (0bamanomics: Trickle Up Poverty.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Toddsterpatriot

Hey Ponnuru: If Helicopter Ben was such a prescient printing press operator, where are the jobs?


6 posted on 04/06/2011 8:34:56 AM PDT by Uncle Miltie (0bamanomics: Trickle Up Poverty.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Toddsterpatriot
Good job on that Monetary Policy, Bernanke!


7 posted on 04/06/2011 8:37:49 AM PDT by Uncle Miltie (0bamanomics: Trickle Up Poverty.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Uncle Miltie
"The possibility that 0bamanomics and 0bamaCare (Fiscal)"

Correction: 0bamanomics (punish success, reward failure) and 0bamaCare (Nationalization of Industry) are not so much a matter of disastrous Federal Government Fiscal Policy as they are the wholesale destruction of motivation, industries and value.

It's kinda hard to think of the proper economic words for such epic and purposeful destruction.

8 posted on 04/06/2011 8:49:12 AM PDT by Uncle Miltie (0bamanomics: Trickle Up Poverty.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 5 | View Replies]

To: Uncle Miltie

No jobs, AND inflation. Way to go Ben! Stagflation!


U.S. consumers face “serious” inflation in the months ahead for clothing, food and other products, the head of Wal-Mart’s U.S. operations warned Wednesday.

The world’s largest retailer is working with suppliers to minimize the effect of cost increases and believes its low-cost business model will position it better than its competitors.

Still, inflation is “going to be serious,” Wal-Mart U.S. CEO Bill Simon said during a meeting with USA TODAY’s editorial board. “We’re seeing cost increases starting to come through at a pretty rapid rate.”

http://www.usatoday.com/money/industries/retail/2011-03-30-wal-mart-ceo-expects-inflation_N.htm


9 posted on 04/06/2011 9:24:24 AM PDT by Uncle Miltie (0bamanomics: Trickle Up Poverty.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 7 | View Replies]

To: Uncle Miltie
Here's the Fiscal picture, which compounds the problem of 1) Loose Money, and 2) 0bamanomics (see above):


10 posted on 04/06/2011 9:30:21 AM PDT by Uncle Miltie (0bamanomics: Trickle Up Poverty.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 8 | View Replies]

To: Toddsterpatriot

bfl


11 posted on 04/06/2011 9:59:14 AM PDT by reed13
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Uncle Miltie
I'm as ardent an opponent of "ObamaCare" as anyone out there, but measuring the macroeconomic effects of it would be an extremely complex endeavor. Your assessment of it would be correct if it involved a massive government intervention in what had been a free-market industry, but that simply is not the case at all. The economics of health care in this country have been so heavily distorted over the last 50+ years that it has been functioning largely outside of any "free market" forces. The entire industry suffers from the same basic flaw as many forms of property/casualty insurance, in that the "natural" relationship of supply/demand and pricing no longer holds because the buyer (a patient) and the seller (a medical professional) no longer deal directly with each other. Instead, they have a provider-customer relationship on paper, but in the vast majority of cases the bills are paid by a third party (either a government agency or an insurance company) who neither provides nor receives the services rendered.

I have no idea what the economic impact of a large-scale nationalization of this "industry" would be. But I can tell you one thing . . . for better or for worse, the shifting of health care costs off the backs of employers will make most industries in this country far more competitive in the long run.

12 posted on 04/06/2011 10:33:46 AM PDT by Alberta's Child ("If you touch my junk, I'm gonna have you arrested.")
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 8 | View Replies]

To: Alberta's Child

Which is why my company is for nationalized health care. It shifts the cost from the company as a whole to the employee as a collective.


13 posted on 04/06/2011 12:05:30 PM PDT by redgolum ("God is dead" -- Nietzsche. "Nietzsche is dead" -- God.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 12 | View Replies]

To: Alberta's Child

My point about 0bamaCare is that Democrats Nationalized Healthcare (and several other industries) in the blink of an eye.

What entrepreneur or businessman will invest in their operations in the U.S., when they can be confiscated in a virtual heart-beat?

Answer: None.

0bamaCare itself, while absolutely horrific on its own merits, is the tip of the iceberg: Potential Governmental theft of anything and everything everywhere all the time.


14 posted on 04/06/2011 12:39:47 PM PDT by Uncle Miltie (0bamanomics: Trickle Up Poverty.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 12 | View Replies]

To: Alberta's Child
"the shifting of health care costs off the backs of employers will make most industries in this country far more competitive in the long run"

We've conversed many times over the years, so I don't mean to be argumentative or offend you. But, consider, please, who WILL pay? Is there some giant pot of 0bamamoney out there that will pay for healthcare so that businesses don't? No.

Within the shores and porous borders of the U.S., there is only us, citizens. We are healthcare consumers, taxpayers, business owners, insurance company employees, government bureaucrats, etc. WE (collectively (oooo, yuck, I hate that word)) will pay for the 0bamanable healthcare, including businesses by having to pay employees enough (pay raises) or governments enough (tax increases) to cover the costs of healthcare. There's no free lunch; business doesn't suddenly become more competitive when costs are merely shifted around the card table from player to player like so many poker chips. The table still has the same number of chips on it; they didn't increase or decrease, and when compared to another table (economically competitive country), the net amount of chips on the table hasn't changed.

I'm amenable to your other arguments about the lack of freedom in healthcare. It all started with one basic flaw: FDR's Wage and Price Controls. Everything else has just been downstream mayhem.

Properly allowed to run, the Free Market would require most people most of the time to pay for healthcare out of pocket at the time of service, like the Dentist, Optometrist, Car Insurance, Life Insurance, or pickles. There would probably be Catastrophic health insurance policies to make sure your family wasn't wiped out by cancer or multiple sclerosis. Charities would spring up to take care of the indigent ill. We used to have these. They were fully privately run charitable hospitals.

Anyhow; that's pretty far afield. If I recall correctly, the origin of this thread is Monetary Policy. I'm going to stay an inflation hawk in spite of Ponnuru.

Be well, and see you around!

15 posted on 04/06/2011 1:17:35 PM PDT by Uncle Miltie (0bamanomics: Trickle Up Poverty.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 12 | View Replies]

To: All; Toddsterpatriot
Congressional Republicans are at the moment blocking... because of their opposition to the inflation they believe is just around the corner.

Overpaid "senior editor" Ramesh Ponnuru must've missed Fed Chair Ben Bernanke talking about inflation happening RIGHT NOW.

16 posted on 04/06/2011 4:08:44 PM PDT by newzjunkey (OBAMA & his DEMOCRAT allies are starving children & killing the elderly.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Uncle Miltie
LOL. Thanks. All good points you raise, but I'll only address one of them so as not to get too far astray from the main topic:

But, consider, please, who WILL pay? Is there some giant pot of 0bamamoney out there that will pay for healthcare so that businesses don't? No.

That's exactly correct. There's no pot of money out there to pay for all this health care, so the demand for health care will decline considerably as individuals are forced to make more and more of these decisions on their own. There never was a "pot of money" to begin with, but people have been living their lives for decades as if there was a pot of money . . . which was fine by them because someone else was always picking up the tab for the medical care.

17 posted on 04/07/2011 10:14:54 AM PDT by Alberta's Child ("If you touch my junk, I'm gonna have you arrested.")
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 15 | View Replies]

To: Alberta's Child

I think we generally agree. Any third party payer virtually eliminates the price constraint on demand, which becomes infinite. The only mechanism to control that infinite demand is rationing, whether by government fiat or insurance company policy guidelines.

I’d rather have the insurance company over the government, but I’d rather have full control myself over even having an insurance company for regular medical bills. We’d all shop and drive down costs!


18 posted on 04/07/2011 10:47:26 AM PDT by Uncle Miltie (0bamanomics: Trickle Up Poverty.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 17 | View Replies]

Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.

Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

FreeRepublic, LLC, PO BOX 9771, FRESNO, CA 93794
FreeRepublic.com is powered by software copyright 2000-2008 John Robinson