Posted on 02/12/2011 6:06:39 AM PST by Notary Sojac
Abraham Lincolns greatest love was politics, but his intellectual passion was for what the 19th century called political economy the way economics and politics intersected in society and government. According to his law partner William Herndon, Lincoln liked political economy, the study of it, and Shelby Cullom, who practiced law beside Lincoln in Springfield, Ill. (and later crafted the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887), thought that theoretically . . . on political economy he was great. Although Lincolns angular, shambling appearance gave him the look of anything but a student of economics one contemporary said he resembled a rough intelligent farmer people quickly found out that any man who took Lincoln for a simple minded man would very soon wake up with his back in a ditch.
Before he was elected the 16th president of the United States, Lincoln ate up, digested, and assimilated the premier texts in 19th-century political economy John Stuart Mills The Principles of Political Economy (1848), Mathew Careys Essays on Political Economy (1822), his son Henry Careys three-volume Principles of Social Science (1858), John Ramsay McCullochs The Principles of Political Economy (1825), and Francis Waylands Elements of Political Economy (1837). These were also the principal statements of classical liberal economics Mill was a protégé of David Ricardo, Henry Carey was the enemy of all interference with the liberty of man to employ his industry in such manner as his instinct of self-interest may dictate, and McCulloch edited an edition of Adam Smith.
Lincoln read and absorbed it all, and it had a profound effect. His embrace of classical-liberal economics was the force that moved all his achievements, from victory in the Civil War to the galaxy of economic policies that emerged from his presidency. And Lincolns principles are the ones most loathed by the progressive Left today. Barack Obama struggled mightily during his presidential campaign to connect his image with that of Lincoln, but Lincolns ideas march against him as surely as the stars march in their courses.
Take the American Revolution to its roots, and you will find it to be a revolution against regulation. Britains imperial planners were originally interested in the New World for the quick riches it might yield. When their colonizing forays produced no such fortunes, they banned the development of all but a handful of manufactures in the colonies, taxed the colonies carrying trade, and labored to convert them into an agricultural resource. The colonists rebelled, and we know with what result.
The Revolution left America independent and without much of a manufacturing sector. This suited Thomas Jefferson, who waxed eloquent about the superior virtues of agrarian life and the corruptions of commerce, but not Alexander Hamilton, who worried that an American republic without the economic strength of manufacturing would be easy pickings whenever some over-mighty European empire grew hungry for adventures in the New World. Jefferson won the initial political argument over the shape of the American economy, but Hamiltons views won the economic argument when the War of 1812 demonstrated just how vulnerable an agrarian republic was to British industrial might.
The next round of this dispute was played out by Andrew Jackson, who shared all of Jeffersons suspicions about commerce and extended them to its twin enablers, banks and corporations, and Henry Clay, who urged the federal government to encourage industrial development through a public-private national bank, direct assistance for building a transportation network (internal improvements, as it was called), and protective tariffs to help industrial start-ups compete with established foreign competitors.
The wild card that roiled these economic disputes was slavery. It coexisted uneasily with commerce, which had little use for slave labor. Slavery prized stability, in which an established hierarchy of great white planters would always rule black slaves, and white yeomen farmers could always be bought off with subsidies (in the form of debtor-relief laws, state laws banning bank and corporate charters, and newer, cheaper land in the West). Andrew Jackson might have railed against those amongst us who wish to enlarge the powers of the General Government, but when it came to slavery, his fellow Democrats did not hesitate to enlarge those powers in order to evict the Cherokee Indians from their tribal lands in Georgia and replace them with plantations, annex Texas as a new slave state, and trigger an expansionist war with Mexico to swell the borders of American slavery. The power to promote economic growth, however, was denounced by Jackson as usurpation and mere selfishness. After all, a federal government that had the power to develop one kind of economic activity, in the form of markets and commerce, might foster experiments in meddling with another slavery.
From his first political stirrings in the early 1830s, Abraham Lincoln never had a doubt where his allegiances lay. Henry Clay, Lincoln said, was my beau ideal of a statesman, and when Lincoln attached himself to Clays newly organized Whig party in the 1830s, he became, a fellow lawyer recalled, as stiff as a man can be in his Whig doctrines. In his first political campaign, in 1832, Lincoln announced that time and experience have verified to a demonstration the public utility of internal improvements. In the state legislature, Lincoln emerged as the Illinois Whigs foremost advocate of a state bank, improved roads and bridges, and the funding of the Illinois & Michigan Canal. He dabbled in commerce himself unsuccessfully, as it turned out but left it to become a lawyer, a profession that was being transformed from its pre-Revolutionary role as the arbiter of community morality into a new one as the enforcer of commercial contracts. His case files, significantly, were almost entirely civil and commercial. Only 6 percent of the cases Lincoln handled were criminal; the largest components of his practice were breach-of-contract suits and debt collections.
Lincolns Whigs were saddled with a reputation, which persists among some modern historians, for being crotchety, negative, and (above all) rich, while the Jacksonian Democrats are cast as the coonskin-wearing sons of the common man. This pushes out of view the embarrassingly large fortunes that sat on the tables of Jacksonian leadership, especially in the slaveholding South. In 1860, two out of every three estates worth more than $100,000 were in the South, and the wealthiest county in the United States was Adams County, in the heart of Democratic Mississippi. And while Andrew Jackson may have been billed as the paladin of Homo democraticus, he had become quite wealthy through land speculation, owned 150 slaves and a 1,000-acre plantation in Tennessee, and enjoyed a continuing major-generals salary that amounted to more than $5,000 per annum (well over $100,000 in todays reckoning).
Nevertheless, Lincolns move to the head of the Illinois Whig party earned him criticism as a sell-out to the aristocracy. It was an accusation he found incredible. A friend recalled decades later that when a rival Democratic politician began raging about the aristocratic pretensions of the Whigs, Lincoln reached over and pulled open the mans vest, and out tumbled the frills of a very un-Democratic ruffle shirt, along with gold watches with large seals hung heavily & massively down. Lincoln pointed out that when his opponent was riding in a fine carriage, wore his kid gloves and had a gold headed cane, he was a poor boy hired on a flat boat at eight dollars a month, and had only one pair of breeches and they were of buckskin. If you call this aristocracy, Lincoln concluded, I plead guilty to the charge.
Lincoln had indeed been a poor boy. Lincolns father, Thomas, was a typical agrarian yeoman, one of the sort that Jefferson described as Gods chosen people, if ever he had a chosen people. A contemporary recalled him as a man satisfied to live in the good old fashioned way so long as his shack kept out the rain and there was plenty of wood to burn. But Thomass son found nothing terribly enchanting about the back-breaking work of the farm or the drunken hooliganism that was its chief entertainment. A friend recalled Lincolns saying that his father taught him to work on the farm but never learned him to love it. Lincoln was always reluctant to talk about his poor-boy origins except when they gave him an opportunity to measure how far he had risen above them. On other occasions, he would sum up his early life in twelve words: I have seen a good deal of the backside of this world. What attracted him to Henry Clay and the Whigs was not elitism but mobility a path, through commerce and finance, out of that backside.
It was also what led him into his lifelong opposition to slavery. I am naturally anti-slavery, he said in 1864. If slavery is not wrong, nothing is wrong. I can not remember when I did not so think, and feel. What he loathed in slavery was not just the physical violence the poor creatures hunted down, and caught, and carried back to their stripes but the economic deadness that confined them to unrewarded toils. He even considered his fathers control over his own labor on the farm to be a species of slavery, so much so that he once announced, I used to be a slave, and now I am so free that they let me practice law.
The antidote to slavery, Lincoln insisted, was also economic: free labor. In the 19th century, free labor was the shorthand term for a particular way of viewing capitalism: as a labor system, in which employers and employees struck bargains for production and wages without restriction, and where the boundaries between these two roles were fluid enough that todays employee could, by dint of energy, talent, and foresight, become the employer of tomorrow.
Slavery was the polar opposite of free labor. With very rare exceptions, it denied the slave any future but that of being a slave, and it replaced the open-ended arrangements of employees and employers with a rigidly dictatorial system. The harmful effects extended beyond the slaves themselves, Lincoln wrote, because in the process, all labor became stigmatized as slave work; the social ideal became the gentleman of leisure who was above and scorned work, rather than men who are industrious, and sober, and honest in the pursuit of their own interests. Men who are industrious that, of course, described Lincoln. Slavery, then, was not merely an abstraction; it was the enemy of every ambition Lincoln had ever felt.
Free labor, however, was ambitions friend. Like Adam Smith, who traced the the real price of everything to the toil and trouble of acquiring it, Lincoln believed that labor laid the foundation for everyone to build up capital of their own. Capital is only the fruit of labor; and could not have existed if labor had not first existed. The folly of slavery lay in its assumption that the vast majority of laborers were indolent and without ambition, that nobody labors unless somebody else, owning capital, somehow by the use of it, induces him to labor. Since by that rule nobody works unless capital excites them to work, the most efficient way to motivate laborers to work is to buy the men and drive them to it, and that is slavery.
In a system of free labor, by contrast, the prospect of profit incites the laborer to work and save, then turn into an entrepreneur himself and hire others to labor. Hiring workers, in turn, not only fires the entrepreneurs ambition, but opens up the path of ambition for his employees, men who have not their own land to work upon, or shops to work in, and who are benefited by working for others.
Lincoln was aware that pro-slavery propagandists had begun claiming in the 1850s that laborers in northern factories were, in reality, no more free to make wage bargains than slaves on southern plantations. In fact, they claimed, free labor was worse off, because employers had no obligation to provide health care for mere wage-earners or to support them in childhood and old age, the way slaveowners did for their slaves.
Lincoln found this comparison absurd, largely because his own life experience refuted it: Twenty-five years ago, I was a hired laborer. A typical young man in this situation, he explained, has for his capital nothing, save two strong hands that God has given him, a heart willing to labor, and a freedom to choose the mode of his work. If the beginner really is willing, however, he works industriously, he behaves soberly, and the result of a year or twos labor is a surplus of capital . . . and in course of time he too has enough capital to hire some new beginner. This, to Lincoln, was the key flaw in the slavery defenders case: Slavery offered no reward at all for sobriety or industry, while free labor was the just and generous, and prosperous system, which opens the way for all gives hope to all, and energy, and progress, and improvement of condition to all.
He did not deny that there were hired men who never became anything more, but that was not because of any defect in free-labor capitalism. If any continue through life in the condition of the hired laborer, it is not the fault of the system, but because of either a dependent nature which prefers it, or improvidence, folly, or singular misfortune. Ambition was not a crime to be punished. We do not propose any war upon capital, he insisted. Far from it: He wanted to allow the humblest man an equal chance to get rich with everybody else and leave each man free to acquire property as fast as he can. The genius of free labor, he explained to an audience of workingmen in New Haven, Conn., was that when one starts poor, as most do in the race of life . . . he knows he can better his condition. Lincoln wanted every man to have the chance and I believe a black man is entitled to it in which he can better his condition. . . . That is the true system . . . and so it may go on and on in one ceaseless round so long as man exists on the face of the earth!
To make this system work, Lincoln envisioned an active role for the federal government, but it was hardly that of a top-down managerial state. The leading principle the sheet anchor of American republicanism, Lincoln said, is that no man is good enough to govern another man, without that others consent. This was what guaranteed individuals . . . the sacred right to regulate their own family affairs and communities . . . [to] arrange their own internal matters to suit themselves without wanton interference by government. The proposition that each man should do precisely as he pleases with all which is exclusively his own was the foundation of the sense of justice there is in me.
So government was not a choice between an all-powerful dictatorship and an anarchistic landscape devoid of highways, traffic signs, levees, and harbor clearance. There were some things that individuals could not accomplish on their own, and it was those things that called governments into being. The legitimate object of government, is to do for a community of people, whatever they need to have done, but can not do, at all, or can not, so well do, for themselves in their separate, and individual capacities, Lincoln wrote. In all that the people can individually do as well for themselves, government ought not to interfere. But in relation to . . . crimes, misdemeanors, and non performance of contracts, and the sort of need that requires combined action, as public roads and highways, public schools, charities, pauperism, orphanage, estates of the deceased, and protection of the machinery of government itself, there still would be some, though not so much, need of government.
Lincolns rule was neither big government nor no government but minimal government, with that minimum confined almost entirely to the task of removing obstacles to self-improvement and the development of ambition. To elevate the condition of men to lift artificial weights from all shoulders to clear the paths of laudable pursuit for all to afford all, an unfettered start, and a fair chance, in the race of life was the leading object of the government. And in the ultimate sense, the Civil War, by preserving the Union and eliminating slavery, was waged in order that each of you may have through this free government . . . an open field and a fair chance for your industry, enterprise and intelligence; that you all may have equal privileges in the race of life, with all its desirable human aspirations. Such a nation is worth fighting for, to secure such an inestimable jewel.
And fight he would: I expect to maintain this contest until successful, or till I die, or am conquered, or my term expires, or Congress or the country forsakes me, Lincoln wrote in 1862. But there were many places to do the fighting, and one of them was Congress (from which almost all the southern Democrats had conveniently withdrawn when their states seceded). The landmark pieces of legislation that he signed between 1861 and 1865 the Homestead Act (1862), the Morrill Land-Grant Colleges Act (1862), the Pacific Railway Act (1862), and the National Bank Act (1863) together with the Morrill Tariff of 1861, which was signed into law by James Buchanan just before he turned the presidency over to Lincoln, amounted to nothing less than a repeal of six decades of Democratic dominance of the federal government. They would have made Lincolns presidency as controversial as Andrew Jacksons even if there had been no Civil War. The railway act, which funded construction of the transcontinental railroad, was the ultimate version of Henry Clays internal improvements, while the tariff hiked import duties to all-time highs to protect American industry. (Lincoln backed the tariffs specifically because of the eras whopping imbalance between European manufacturing and American manufacturing; whether he would have advocated their extension permanently is another matter.) In 1862 the Indiana Democratic state committee complained that Lincoln had struck down at one dash all the labor of Gen. Jackson for the last four years of his administration.
Did this amount to big government? Not if we measure bigness by the size of the federal budget. In 1860, federal spending amounted to a minuscule $63.2 million. Factored for a century and a half of inflation, the modern equivalent would be a federal budget of about $1.5 billion. During Lincolns presidency, federal spending leapt from $66.6 million in 1861 to $1.29 billion in 1865. But even with the swollen costs of war to absorb, the 1865 federal budget would translate into only about $18 billion in todays money, using consumer-price inflation as the measure.
The bulk of that spending was war-related, and disappeared as soon as the wartime emergency was over. By 1871, the federal budget had shrunk to $293 million only 22.7 percent of the size it had been in 1865 and it would have shrunk even more drastically if not for the cost of servicing the wartime debt (which accounted for 44 percent of the budget) and paying pensions to wounded and injured soldiers (another 11 percent). Lincoln was dead by then, of course, but his successors and the Congress had generally followed his intentions. If Lincolns goal was to use the Civil War as the cloak for a permanent transformation of the federal government into an all-powerful megastate, the budget numbers certainly do not show much evidence of it.
The Italian historian Raimondo Luraghi once remarked that, unlike the Lincoln administration, the Confederate rulers did not want a private capitalist industry and did not want to see a powerful industrial bourgeoisie rising in the Confederacy. So while the Union government contracted out its wartime needs to the private sector, the Confederate government set up government-owned supply facilities investing millions of dollars, arming and supplying one of the largest armies in the world and all this as national property or under national control, in a kind of quasi-socialist management. Predictably, the Confederacys nationalized industries did a bad job of supplying and feeding the rebel armies, so among the reasons Luraghi listed for the Confederacys downfall was its choice of the way of state socialism, a solution that is as far from capitalism as the earth is from the moon.
But the fundamental convictions that animated the Slave Power that stability is preferable to mobility, and that top-down management in the name of efficiency and fairness is the default position of human society were not among the things surrendered at Appomattox. Half a century after Lincolns death, another American president would contradict every principle in political economy that Lincoln held dear by announcing that society must stop modeling itself on metaphors like the race of life and instead become a family . . . where men can live as a single community, co-operative as in a perfected, coordinated beehive, not afraid of any storm of nature, and do so with an eye single to the standards of justice and fair play. What a century of Woodrow Wilsons family metaphor has produced, however, is the dreary reality of a government that regards citizens as miscreant children requiring constant correction of their appetites, salaries, attitudes, vocabulary, and even light bulbs.
Hurling Lincolns economic principles back against this present-day reality may seem like the height of futility. How many battalions, we may ask, do the economic ideas of a man dead for a century and a half command? But those inclined to dismiss these ideas should beware of Lincolns ditch. A generation from now, the question might seem more serious.Abraham Lincolns greatest love was politics, but his intellectual passion was for what the 19th century called political economy the way economics and politics intersected in society and government. According to his law partner William Herndon, Lincoln liked political economy, the study of it, and Shelby Cullom, who practiced law beside Lincoln in Springfield, Ill. (and later crafted the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887), thought that theoretically . . . on political economy he was great. Although Lincolns angular, shambling appearance gave him the look of anything but a student of economics one contemporary said he resembled a rough intelligent farmer people quickly found out that any man who took Lincoln for a simple minded man would very soon wake up with his back in a ditch.
Before he was elected the 16th president of the United States, Lincoln ate up, digested, and assimilated the premier texts in 19th-century political economy John Stuart Mills The Principles of Political Economy (1848), Mathew Careys Essays on Political Economy (1822), his son Henry Careys three-volume Principles of Social Science (1858), John Ramsay McCullochs The Principles of Political Economy (1825), and Francis Waylands Elements of Political Economy (1837). These were also the principal statements of classical liberal economics Mill was a protégé of David Ricardo, Henry Carey was the enemy of all interference with the liberty of man to employ his industry in such manner as his instinct of self-interest may dictate, and McCulloch edited an edition of Adam Smith.
Lincoln read and absorbed it all, and it had a profound effect. His embrace of classical-liberal economics was the force that moved all his achievements, from victory in the Civil War to the galaxy of economic policies that emerged from his presidency. And Lincolns principles are the ones most loathed by the progressive Left today. Barack Obama struggled mightily during his presidential campaign to connect his image with that of Lincoln, but Lincolns ideas march against him as surely as the stars march in their courses.
Take the American Revolution to its roots, and you will find it to be a revolution against regulation. Britains imperial planners were originally interested in the New World for the quick riches it might yield. When their colonizing forays produced no such fortunes, they banned the development of all but a handful of manufactures in the colonies, taxed the colonies carrying trade, and labored to convert them into an agricultural resource. The colonists rebelled, and we know with what result.
The Revolution left America independent and without much of a manufacturing sector. This suited Thomas Jefferson, who waxed eloquent about the superior virtues of agrarian life and the corruptions of commerce, but not Alexander Hamilton, who worried that an American republic without the economic strength of manufacturing would be easy pickings whenever some over-mighty European empire grew hungry for adventures in the New World. Jefferson won the initial political argument over the shape of the American economy, but Hamiltons views won the economic argument when the War of 1812 demonstrated just how vulnerable an agrarian republic was to British industrial might.
The next round of this dispute was played out by Andrew Jackson, who shared all of Jeffersons suspicions about commerce and extended them to its twin enablers, banks and corporations, and Henry Clay, who urged the federal government to encourage industrial development through a public-private national bank, direct assistance for building a transportation network (internal improvements, as it was called), and protective tariffs to help industrial start-ups compete with established foreign competitors.
The wild card that roiled these economic disputes was slavery. It coexisted uneasily with commerce, which had little use for slave labor. Slavery prized stability, in which an established hierarchy of great white planters would always rule black slaves, and white yeomen farmers could always be bought off with subsidies (in the form of debtor-relief laws, state laws banning bank and corporate charters, and newer, cheaper land in the West). Andrew Jackson might have railed against those amongst us who wish to enlarge the powers of the General Government, but when it came to slavery, his fellow Democrats did not hesitate to enlarge those powers in order to evict the Cherokee Indians from their tribal lands in Georgia and replace them with plantations, annex Texas as a new slave state, and trigger an expansionist war with Mexico to swell the borders of American slavery. The power to promote economic growth, however, was denounced by Jackson as usurpation and mere selfishness. After all, a federal government that had the power to develop one kind of economic activity, in the form of markets and commerce, might foster experiments in meddling with another slavery.
From his first political stirrings in the early 1830s, Abraham Lincoln never had a doubt where his allegiances lay. Henry Clay, Lincoln said, was my beau ideal of a statesman, and when Lincoln attached himself to Clays newly organized Whig party in the 1830s, he became, a fellow lawyer recalled, as stiff as a man can be in his Whig doctrines. In his first political campaign, in 1832, Lincoln announced that time and experience have verified to a demonstration the public utility of internal improvements. In the state legislature, Lincoln emerged as the Illinois Whigs foremost advocate of a state bank, improved roads and bridges, and the funding of the Illinois & Michigan Canal. He dabbled in commerce himself unsuccessfully, as it turned out but left it to become a lawyer, a profession that was being transformed from its pre-Revolutionary role as the arbiter of community morality into a new one as the enforcer of commercial contracts. His case files, significantly, were almost entirely civil and commercial. Only 6 percent of the cases Lincoln handled were criminal; the largest components of his practice were breach-of-contract suits and debt collections.
Lincolns Whigs were saddled with a reputation, which persists among some modern historians, for being crotchety, negative, and (above all) rich, while the Jacksonian Democrats are cast as the coonskin-wearing sons of the common man. This pushes out of view the embarrassingly large fortunes that sat on the tables of Jacksonian leadership, especially in the slaveholding South. In 1860, two out of every three estates worth more than $100,000 were in the South, and the wealthiest county in the United States was Adams County, in the heart of Democratic Mississippi. And while Andrew Jackson may have been billed as the paladin of Homo democraticus, he had become quite wealthy through land speculation, owned 150 slaves and a 1,000-acre plantation in Tennessee, and enjoyed a continuing major-generals salary that amounted to more than $5,000 per annum (well over $100,000 in todays reckoning).
Nevertheless, Lincolns move to the head of the Illinois Whig party earned him criticism as a sell-out to the aristocracy. It was an accusation he found incredible. A friend recalled decades later that when a rival Democratic politician began raging about the aristocratic pretensions of the Whigs, Lincoln reached over and pulled open the mans vest, and out tumbled the frills of a very un-Democratic ruffle shirt, along with gold watches with large seals hung heavily & massively down. Lincoln pointed out that when his opponent was riding in a fine carriage, wore his kid gloves and had a gold headed cane, he was a poor boy hired on a flat boat at eight dollars a month, and had only one pair of breeches and they were of buckskin. If you call this aristocracy, Lincoln concluded, I plead guilty to the charge.
Lincoln had indeed been a poor boy. Lincolns father, Thomas, was a typical agrarian yeoman, one of the sort that Jefferson described as Gods chosen people, if ever he had a chosen people. A contemporary recalled him as a man satisfied to live in the good old fashioned way so long as his shack kept out the rain and there was plenty of wood to burn. But Thomass son found nothing terribly enchanting about the back-breaking work of the farm or the drunken hooliganism that was its chief entertainment. A friend recalled Lincolns saying that his father taught him to work on the farm but never learned him to love it. Lincoln was always reluctant to talk about his poor-boy origins except when they gave him an opportunity to measure how far he had risen above them. On other occasions, he would sum up his early life in twelve words: I have seen a good deal of the backside of this world. What attracted him to Henry Clay and the Whigs was not elitism but mobility a path, through commerce and finance, out of that backside.
It was also what led him into his lifelong opposition to slavery. I am naturally anti-slavery, he said in 1864. If slavery is not wrong, nothing is wrong. I can not remember when I did not so think, and feel. What he loathed in slavery was not just the physical violence the poor creatures hunted down, and caught, and carried back to their stripes but the economic deadness that confined them to unrewarded toils. He even considered his fathers control over his own labor on the farm to be a species of slavery, so much so that he once announced, I used to be a slave, and now I am so free that they let me practice law.
The antidote to slavery, Lincoln insisted, was also economic: free labor. In the 19th century, free labor was the shorthand term for a particular way of viewing capitalism: as a labor system, in which employers and employees struck bargains for production and wages without restriction, and where the boundaries between these two roles were fluid enough that todays employee could, by dint of energy, talent, and foresight, become the employer of tomorrow.
Slavery was the polar opposite of free labor. With very rare exceptions, it denied the slave any future but that of being a slave, and it replaced the open-ended arrangements of employees and employers with a rigidly dictatorial system. The harmful effects extended beyond the slaves themselves, Lincoln wrote, because in the process, all labor became stigmatized as slave work; the social ideal became the gentleman of leisure who was above and scorned work, rather than men who are industrious, and sober, and honest in the pursuit of their own interests. Men who are industrious that, of course, described Lincoln. Slavery, then, was not merely an abstraction; it was the enemy of every ambition Lincoln had ever felt.
Free labor, however, was ambitions friend. Like Adam Smith, who traced the the real price of everything to the toil and trouble of acquiring it, Lincoln believed that labor laid the foundation for everyone to build up capital of their own. Capital is only the fruit of labor; and could not have existed if labor had not first existed. The folly of slavery lay in its assumption that the vast majority of laborers were indolent and without ambition, that nobody labors unless somebody else, owning capital, somehow by the use of it, induces him to labor. Since by that rule nobody works unless capital excites them to work, the most efficient way to motivate laborers to work is to buy the men and drive them to it, and that is slavery.
In a system of free labor, by contrast, the prospect of profit incites the laborer to work and save, then turn into an entrepreneur himself and hire others to labor. Hiring workers, in turn, not only fires the entrepreneurs ambition, but opens up the path of ambition for his employees, men who have not their own land to work upon, or shops to work in, and who are benefited by working for others.
Lincoln was aware that pro-slavery propagandists had begun claiming in the 1850s that laborers in northern factories were, in reality, no more free to make wage bargains than slaves on southern plantations. In fact, they claimed, free labor was worse off, because employers had no obligation to provide health care for mere wage-earners or to support them in childhood and old age, the way slaveowners did for their slaves.
Lincoln found this comparison absurd, largely because his own life experience refuted it: Twenty-five years ago, I was a hired laborer. A typical young man in this situation, he explained, has for his capital nothing, save two strong hands that God has given him, a heart willing to labor, and a freedom to choose the mode of his work. If the beginner really is willing, however, he works industriously, he behaves soberly, and the result of a year or twos labor is a surplus of capital . . . and in course of time he too has enough capital to hire some new beginner. This, to Lincoln, was the key flaw in the slavery defenders case: Slavery offered no reward at all for sobriety or industry, while free labor was the just and generous, and prosperous system, which opens the way for all gives hope to all, and energy, and progress, and improvement of condition to all.
He did not deny that there were hired men who never became anything more, but that was not because of any defect in free-labor capitalism. If any continue through life in the condition of the hired laborer, it is not the fault of the system, but because of either a dependent nature which prefers it, or improvidence, folly, or singular misfortune. Ambition was not a crime to be punished. We do not propose any war upon capital, he insisted. Far from it: He wanted to allow the humblest man an equal chance to get rich with everybody else and leave each man free to acquire property as fast as he can. The genius of free labor, he explained to an audience of workingmen in New Haven, Conn., was that when one starts poor, as most do in the race of life . . . he knows he can better his condition. Lincoln wanted every man to have the chance and I believe a black man is entitled to it in which he can better his condition. . . . That is the true system . . . and so it may go on and on in one ceaseless round so long as man exists on the face of the earth!
To make this system work, Lincoln envisioned an active role for the federal government, but it was hardly that of a top-down managerial state. The leading principle the sheet anchor of American republicanism, Lincoln said, is that no man is good enough to govern another man, without that others consent. This was what guaranteed individuals . . . the sacred right to regulate their own family affairs and communities . . . [to] arrange their own internal matters to suit themselves without wanton interference by government. The proposition that each man should do precisely as he pleases with all which is exclusively his own was the foundation of the sense of justice there is in me.
So government was not a choice between an all-powerful dictatorship and an anarchistic landscape devoid of highways, traffic signs, levees, and harbor clearance. There were some things that individuals could not accomplish on their own, and it was those things that called governments into being. The legitimate object of government, is to do for a community of people, whatever they need to have done, but can not do, at all, or can not, so well do, for themselves in their separate, and individual capacities, Lincoln wrote. In all that the people can individually do as well for themselves, government ought not to interfere. But in relation to . . . crimes, misdemeanors, and non performance of contracts, and the sort of need that requires combined action, as public roads and highways, public schools, charities, pauperism, orphanage, estates of the deceased, and protection of the machinery of government itself, there still would be some, though not so much, need of government.
Lincolns rule was neither big government nor no government but minimal government, with that minimum confined almost entirely to the task of removing obstacles to self-improvement and the development of ambition. To elevate the condition of men to lift artificial weights from all shoulders to clear the paths of laudable pursuit for all to afford all, an unfettered start, and a fair chance, in the race of life was the leading object of the government. And in the ultimate sense, the Civil War, by preserving the Union and eliminating slavery, was waged in order that each of you may have through this free government . . . an open field and a fair chance for your industry, enterprise and intelligence; that you all may have equal privileges in the race of life, with all its desirable human aspirations. Such a nation is worth fighting for, to secure such an inestimable jewel.
And fight he would: I expect to maintain this contest until successful, or till I die, or am conquered, or my term expires, or Congress or the country forsakes me, Lincoln wrote in 1862. But there were many places to do the fighting, and one of them was Congress (from which almost all the southern Democrats had conveniently withdrawn when their states seceded). The landmark pieces of legislation that he signed between 1861 and 1865 the Homestead Act (1862), the Morrill Land-Grant Colleges Act (1862), the Pacific Railway Act (1862), and the National Bank Act (1863) together with the Morrill Tariff of 1861, which was signed into law by James Buchanan just before he turned the presidency over to Lincoln, amounted to nothing less than a repeal of six decades of Democratic dominance of the federal government. They would have made Lincolns presidency as controversial as Andrew Jacksons even if there had been no Civil War. The railway act, which funded construction of the transcontinental railroad, was the ultimate version of Henry Clays internal improvements, while the tariff hiked import duties to all-time highs to protect American industry. (Lincoln backed the tariffs specifically because of the eras whopping imbalance between European manufacturing and American manufacturing; whether he would have advocated their extension permanently is another matter.) In 1862 the Indiana Democratic state committee complained that Lincoln had struck down at one dash all the labor of Gen. Jackson for the last four years of his administration.
Did this amount to big government? Not if we measure bigness by the size of the federal budget. In 1860, federal spending amounted to a minuscule $63.2 million. Factored for a century and a half of inflation, the modern equivalent would be a federal budget of about $1.5 billion. During Lincolns presidency, federal spending leapt from $66.6 million in 1861 to $1.29 billion in 1865. But even with the swollen costs of war to absorb, the 1865 federal budget would translate into only about $18 billion in todays money, using consumer-price inflation as the measure.
The bulk of that spending was war-related, and disappeared as soon as the wartime emergency was over. By 1871, the federal budget had shrunk to $293 million only 22.7 percent of the size it had been in 1865 and it would have shrunk even more drastically if not for the cost of servicing the wartime debt (which accounted for 44 percent of the budget) and paying pensions to wounded and injured soldiers (another 11 percent). Lincoln was dead by then, of course, but his successors and the Congress had generally followed his intentions. If Lincolns goal was to use the Civil War as the cloak for a permanent transformation of the federal government into an all-powerful megastate, the budget numbers certainly do not show much evidence of it.
The Italian historian Raimondo Luraghi once remarked that, unlike the Lincoln administration, the Confederate rulers did not want a private capitalist industry and did not want to see a powerful industrial bourgeoisie rising in the Confederacy. So while the Union government contracted out its wartime needs to the private sector, the Confederate government set up government-owned supply facilities investing millions of dollars, arming and supplying one of the largest armies in the world and all this as national property or under national control, in a kind of quasi-socialist management. Predictably, the Confederacys nationalized industries did a bad job of supplying and feeding the rebel armies, so among the reasons Luraghi listed for the Confederacys downfall was its choice of the way of state socialism, a solution that is as far from capitalism as the earth is from the moon.
But the fundamental convictions that animated the Slave Power that stability is preferable to mobility, and that top-down management in the name of efficiency and fairness is the default position of human society were not among the things surrendered at Appomattox. Half a century after Lincolns death, another American president would contradict every principle in political economy that Lincoln held dear by announcing that society must stop modeling itself on metaphors like the race of life and instead become a family . . . where men can live as a single community, co-operative as in a perfected, coordinated beehive, not afraid of any storm of nature, and do so with an eye single to the standards of justice and fair play. What a century of Woodrow Wilsons family metaphor has produced, however, is the dreary reality of a government that regards citizens as miscreant children requiring constant correction of their appetites, salaries, attitudes, vocabulary, and even light bulbs.
Hurling Lincolns economic principles back against this present-day reality may seem like the height of futility. How many battalions, we may ask, do the economic ideas of a man dead for a century and a half command? But those inclined to dismiss these ideas should beware of Lincolns ditch. A generation from now, the question might seem more serious.
Go look at a copy of the confederate constitution...better yet, let me save you the trouble:
No bill of attainder, ex post facto law, or law denying or impairing the right of property in negro slaves shall be passed [by Congress]
The only thing the confederacy sought to escape was responsibility. They created a virtual carbon copy of the US Constitution - with one singular exception - they inserted language memorializing the perpetual ownership of other human beings. At a time when the civilized world was rejecting slavery the south sought to perpetuate and expand the activity.
As for defending itself, it should have thought of that before it initiated the hostilities.
Fine, then it shouldn't have been too much trouble to cite in the first place.
Remember, we've seen Wlat and capitan_refugio's "quoting" style before.
[You, dissembling] Says Foghorn Leghorn, who always gets lost in his own ranting rhetoric.
I notice that you forgot to deny the charge, that you use "slavery" as a bludgeon just like the Abolitionists did, i.e. dishonestly, and patently so since there is no slavery in the United States, and yet you continually try to attach it to people who disagree with you and object to your sectionalist diatribes.
As for my posts, please show me an example of a "ranting rhetoric" that your fevered imagination tells you I posted.
[Me] You throw the word "slaver" around as if you thought it had a Velcro backing.
[You, dissembling some more] I don't recall every having used the word "slaver." Not my style.
Oh, you don't? "I ..... forgot!!" </Steve Martin>
And yet you continue to use slavery as a moral club, as if simply writing "slavery" transmutes dross into gold, and falsifies everything other people tell you about American history. Used in that way, it becomes an ad hominem argument, and you use it to blackguard people living and dead who never owned a slave.
[Thee] Perhaps not initially, but we do know that the south's war was to perpetuate and expand the institution of slavery.
Actually, no. The South attempted to do that from 1850 until the election of Lincoln. Then the Southern States left the Union, abandoning (as far as I can tell) the Territories whose slavery status had been in dispute. As far as I can tell, only Missouri and New Mexico were fought-over by the Confederacy. They made a weak attempt to organize a Confederate territorial government in Arizona but failed. Missouri had been a slave State, but its government was removed by Abraham Lincoln through surrogates mounting a coup d'etat in the name of "loyalty to the Union" (as if Missouri owed that, when Missouri was being maltreated along with the rest of the Southern States) and turned into a battlefield.
Southerners wanted the same rights everyone else had, to migrate west and take their property, their slaves, with them. Whereas Lincoln wanted the Territories for his constituents, exclusively. Not only did Lincoln and the other Free Soil enthusiasts not want slaves in the Territories, but they didn't want Southerners either -- because Southerners didn't have their mahnds raaht on the subject of slavery, and might vote wrong if the matter were put to a vote under "popular sovereignty" doctrines.
That's what the Jayhawkers and Potawatomie Creek were about. The Free Soilers and John Brown didn't kill slaves, they killed Southerners.
As the saying goes, "There it is."
Actually yes. Any attempt to imply that the south abandoned the territories is blatantly dishonest. Their efforts or desires for expansion didn't fail for lack of trying.
Arizona: There wasn't a "weak attempt" at seizing Arizona. Once Texas turned Arizona was left to its own devices and soon sided with the rebels. Significant portions of (populated) Arizona considered itself part of the confederacy until the end of the war.
New Mexico: In July 23, 1861 the rebs invaded New Mexico and seized control. They lasted a year.
Kansas: We all know of the conflicts in Kansas. Those conflicts ran the course of the war.
California: The confederacy had aspirations of conquest of California and for a short while saw the gateway states of Arizona and New Mexico as stepping stones towards that goal. The fact is that there were skirmishes between loyalists and secessionists in every part of the country and the territories throughout the war.
Shall I go on?
Southerners wanted the same rights everyone else had, to migrate west and take their property, their slaves, with them. Whereas Lincoln wanted the Territories for his constituents, exclusively. Not only did Lincoln and the other Free Soil enthusiasts not want slaves in the Territories, but they didn't want Southerners either -- because Southerners didn't have their mahnds raaht on the subject of slavery, and might vote wrong if the matter were put to a vote under "popular sovereignty" doctrines.
As the saying goes, "What a crock."
This is what people get for being halfway polite to you. Let you in the house, you promptly take a dump on the rug.
Your statement is false on its face. And even if you were, by some miracle of forensics, to show that the South did not abandon Kansas, Nebraska, Colorado, the Dakotas, and everything north and west of them, you would still be light-years from showing dishonesty in the argument of an interlocutor who disagreed with you. What swinishness.
There wasn't a "weak attempt" at seizing Arizona.
Oh, really? How many brigades did Jeff Davis devote to that enterprise? On the other hand, federal troops from California were soon in evidence, and the Texans disappeared back east.
New Mexico: .....
If you had read my post for comprehension, you would have noticed that I excepted New Mexico from my generalization.
Kansas: We all know of the conflicts in Kansas.
You post as if you didn't. Guerrilla warfare is not an attempt to exert military and civil control. The South was never in a position to exert control, and did not attempt it. Vendetta and low-intensity conflict was all that Kansas saw. Pennsylvania saw three full-sized corps on its territory, and yet nobody asserts that Lee ever tried to wrest Pennsylvania from the Union. Post like you know the difference between fact and polemic.
Shall I go on?
Not like that. You're embarrassing me, and here I thought I didn't care. Just quit while you're behind. This is .... sad.
Pardon us for not being familiar with Guelzo; I had to look him up in Wiki and the W.E.B. DuBois Institute at Harvard, where Guelzo has a vita posted (why, I'm not sure, I couldn't see him listed as a Fellow, although he'd studied at Harvard). So granted that Guelzo, as the holder of an endowed chair (named for Henry Luce) at Gettysburg College, has chops and awards as a writer, it's still true that he writes down one side of the page, as a Unionist memorializer of Lincoln and his athloi on behalf of the proprietors of the Gilded Age.
It would have been nice, though, if Guelzo, knowing that National Review doesn't footnote, had provided a little context for some of his quotes -- although that might have been difficult, given his extensive use of them.
That all said, Guelzo's claims that Lincoln was an antisocialist and that the National Democracy was the forerunner, the spiritual cradle, of today's neo-Stalinists, are novel to say the least. One senses a stretch in pursuit of a cribbed point here, and so it'll have to be argued out.
One notices, too, that Guelzo confines his discussion of Lincoln's economic ideas to the sphere of books and public legislation, and does not show how it's of a piece with Lincoln's toleration and even fostering of access-capitalists and war profiteers like Ben Butler who were involved in the clandestine cotton trade through the front lines and the business of buying up confiscated Confederate properties that Lincoln taxed precisely so they could be confiscated -- demanding in his legislation that the taxes be paid in person, even by serving Confederate officers. Which doesn't exactly strike me as the kind of classical economic liberalism Ayn Rand would endorse.
YAWN. So says the boss hog.
Actually weather Lincoln intended to free the slaves or not was mute once the south seceded, they choose the path for freeing the slaves, they decided Mr. Lincoln would have to do it by force of arms rather than in Congress.
“...the south seceded, they choose the path for freeing the slaves...”
-
Oh, so it was the south that freed the slaves?
That’s some pretty twisted thinking right there.
(Yes, that was sarcasm.)
The results were the same, one way or another Lincoln was going to end slavery, it was the south that decided the path would be through bloodshed and rebellion.
It was the south that decided the course they would take,
they decided to secede,
they decided to capture all the federal guns and ammo they could laid their hands on
they decided to attack Fort Sumpter,
the south decided the cost of slavery was worth a war instead of a political defeat in the halls of congress.
Lincoln had them by the political short hairs and they knew it.
Hey Foghorn:
When it comes to making up sh!t about the conflict between North and South, you are the reigning lightweight champion.
Quotes and links available on request.
Please cite just one example on FR of the acceptability or tolerance of slavery. Just one.
Now, do you agree with me that this is acceptance of slavery? I personally think this is not only acceptance, but borders on endorsement, particularly taking into account that the slave system was becoming increasingly more, not less, repressive in the 1850's.
If you don't agree, then we can have that discussion right here in this thread.
If you do agree, then I can find those threads, but knowing the FR search system, don't expect it to happen within the next few hours.
A great essay.
This country was partially built on slave economics, both north and South. What you yankees have tried to do is hide your willing and profitable participation in slavery through historical revisionism. Slavery in the North
The Confederates not only wanted to repeal the 10th Amendment but they wanted to repeal the entire Constitution.
The South responded to Constitutional violations and intended violations by the north and Lincoln's regime. If you want to flap your jaws about repealing the Constitution, look towards Lincoln.
They also continually waged a poitical war against the Constitution that wanted to secede from so long ago.
Would you care to be specific on this point or, like most of you northern hotheads, do you just throw crap against the wall and see what sticks?
From the Confederate democrats to todays Progressive democrats the legacy of your party has always been the same.
My party? What party would that be?
Rebellion, Slavery economics, and a complete lack of morality. This is the legacy of the Confederate democrats.
Illegal war, subjugation, slavery economics and a complete lack of morality is an accurate description of you damnyankees.
The Confederate democrats tried to secede fro the Constitution and then Wilson, the Progressive democrat who had the support of Confederates, was the first President to denounce the ideology of the Framers.
Wilson was a product of one of your revered northeast Ivy League schools, the same schools that pump out the rest of your yankee heros such as obama, clinton, kerry, et al.
What you yankee mythologists refuse to acknowledge is that the Lincoln regime was the tip of the socialistic sword. The northeast, along with their wescoast liberal comrades, have been trying to socialize the US for 150 years and the South is the only reason that the northeast isn't a communist dictatorship.
Now there's a reality that'll make a few folks choke.
As my last post demonstrates, it was the Confederacy that set up a socialist state, not the North.
And, as the essayist further explains, the federal budget contracted after the war greatly.
Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.