Posted on 10/10/2006 8:59:26 AM PDT by cryptical
Advocates of replacing the income tax with the FairTax a consumption tax in the form of a national retail sales tax (NRST) on new goods and services regularly point to the complexity of the tax code, the millions of hours and dollars wasted on compliance costs, the evils of the withholding tax, and the abuses of the IRS to bolster their case for the FairTax.
The twin truths that taxation is theft (no matter how the money is collected) and that the US government should never be given a budget that is in the trillions (no matter how the money is collected) are concepts that FairTax proponents have never grasped.
The FairTax is intended to be revenue neutral; that is, the federal leviathan and all of its programs will receive exactly the same amount of funding as under the current tax system. Federal spending will remain at the same obscene level that it is now. This means that, although conceivably some people might pay the same amount in taxes under the FairTax plan that they do now, some will pay more and others will pay less.
Or, if we accept without reservation the claim of FairTax supporters that tax evaders, tax avoiders, workers in the underground economy, and others who don't pay their "fair" share will now be "caught," therefore increasing the tax base, we can, for the sake of argument, say that some people might pay the same amount in taxes, many will pay less, and the few that will pay more are the ones who were paying little or no taxes to begin with.
But even though the things that FairTax proponents say about the tax code, compliance costs, the withholding tax, and the IRS are certainly true, what most people care about is the bottom line. If an individual's taxes were lowered but the prices of all goods and services were at the same time raised, lower taxes might actually be a curse instead of a blessing.
The question is therefore not one of paying higher or lower taxes, but instead: Will I have more money remaining from my paycheck to save, invest, or spend on vacations and luxury items under the FairTax plan after I pay my bills and make my necessary purchases?
This is a question that FairTax activists have answered in the affirmative.
The FairTax Plan
Under the FairTax proposal, there will no longer be Social Security and Medicare taxes, withholding taxes, corporate taxes, gift taxes, estate taxes, capital gains taxes, and personal income taxes. However, these will all be replaced with a national sales tax on all new goods and services. But never fear, says the FairTax advocate, even with this sales tax, the prices of most goods and services will still be about the same.
As talk show host Neal Boortz [1]claims in The FairTax Book: "The prices of consumer goods and services remain essentially the same, with the removal of the embedded taxes compensating for the added consumption tax." The embedded costs of taxes in all consumer goods and services drive up prices because they increase the costs of doing business of manufacturers and service providers. As Boortz explains about suppliers of goods and services:
When you buy that loaf of bread, you're paying a portion of all of the bills, including tax bills, of every person or business entity that had anything to do with that bread, from before the wheat was planted up until the loaf of bread ends up in that plastic bag in the back seat of your minivan.
Have you thought about how much your doctor pays into the payroll tax system to augment his or her employees' Social Security and Medicare taxes? And what about all the embedded taxes your doctor paid when purchasing all of that sophisticated equipment, not to mention the endless monthly outlay for cotton swabs and tongue depressors?
Compliance costs are also "costs that are ultimately embedded in retail prices paid by consumers." Boortz's coauthor, Congressman John Linder (R-GA), in his November 5, 2003, testimonyin behalf of the FairTax before the Joint Economic Committee on " Rethinking the Tax Code," stated that "because of the tax component incorporated into prices under the current income tax code, we are already paying the equivalent of the FairTax!" This must include the prices of all goods and services, for Boortz maintains that "like retail goods, new homes won't be any more expensive, even with the FairTax added."
The rate of the NRST under the FairTax is supposed to be 23 percent. But as I have already shown in my first article on the FairTax (" The Fair Tax Fraud"), that is just the initial rate it will be adjusted upward every year. And as I have already shown in my review of Boortz's book (" There Is No Such Thing as a Fair Tax"), the stated rate of 23 percent is really 30 percent the new math used by FairTax proponents figures the rate inclusively (the tax is included in the price of the product) rather than exclusively (the tax is added to the price of the product).
To offset the full amount of this sales tax, retail prices would have to fall by a like amount if the prices of most goods and services are to "remain essentially the same." This is exactly what Boortz asserts will happen after the FairTax plan is implemented:
One of the beauties of the FairTax is that the price of consumer goods and services in our economy will go down by roughly the same amount as the proposed FairTax rate of 23 percent. This very nearly makes everything a wash.
Consumers of all incomes will be paying at least 20 percent less for virtually everything they buy, including the basics of food, clothing, shelter, and transportation.
And how does Boortz know that this will happen? Why, Dr. Dale Jorgenson said so or at least that's what Boortz claims. Back in 1997, Jorgenson, the former chairman of the Harvard Economics Department, authored a report for Americans for Fair Taxation (AFT) entitled "The Economic Impact of the National Retail Sales Tax." [2]Before writing his 1997 report for the AFT, Jorgenson had testified before the House Committee on Ways and Means in 1995 on "The Economic Impact of Fundamental Tax Reform" and in 1996 on "The Economic Impact of Taxing Consumption." [3]
Referring to this study, Boortz says: "On average, Jorgenson concluded, 22 percent of the price paid for a consumer product represents embedded taxes. That means that for every dollar you spend on a loaf of bread, twenty-two cents ends up being passed on to the government somewhere along the line in the form of taxes." Congressman Linder also referred to this report in his 2003 testimony before the Joint Economic Committee: "The FairTax plan creates transparency within the tax code. It eliminates the hidden tax component from the prices of goods. According to a Harvard study, the current tax component in our price system averages 22 percent."
Boortz believes that prices will fall because "if these embedded taxes were to disappear that is, if the tax burdens of all the corporations, businesses, and individuals involved in the manufacture, marketing, and sale of these items were to be removed these businesses would experience an immediate increase in their profit margins that would roughly equal that 22 percent." Then, once profit margins increase, Boortz presumes that "competitive market pressures" would "force prices down to a level where corporate profit margins are pretty much where they were before the passage of the FairTax." Linder likewise testified that competition would "bring prices down an average of 20-30 percent."
But this isn't all that Boortz has promised, for under the FairTax system everyone will get a raise because everyone will be able to keep his whole paycheck:
Once the FairTax takes effect, you'll be receiving 100 percent of every paycheck, with no withholding of federal income taxes, Social Security taxes, or Medicare taxes.
The poor along with everybody else will no longer have Social Security taxes or Medicare taxes withheld from their paychecks. Whatever they earn, they get on payday. For most of those we categorize as poor, this would mean an immediate 25 to 30 percent increase in their take-home pay.
We start collecting 100 percent of our earnings on our paycheck.
We all get virtual raises, since payroll taxes are no longer siphoned from our checks.
But as we shall presently see, these four statements turned out to be lies and were subsequently altered or omitted in the new paperback edition of The FairTax Book.
Boortz has seriously misread and/or misrepresented Jorgenson in four key areas.
Boortz's First Misrepresentation
Boortz's first misrepresentation concerns the rate of the FairTax. He maintains that in order to be revenue neutral the tax rate would have to be 23 percent figured inclusively or 30 percent figured exclusively. But here is what Jorgenson actually said:
The imposition of the NRST would produce a sharply higher tax rate on consumer goods and services, but the tenth chart shows that the initial consumption tax rate would be twenty-three percent at both federal and state and local levels or only 18.4 percent at the federal level. This would gradually rise over time, but remain below thirty percent or 23.8 percent at the federal level.
Unlike Boortz, Jorgenson does not give us any baloney about inclusive and exclusive tax rates. But note that Jorgenson's rate of 23 percent includes federal, state, and local taxes. This is because of one of Jorgenson's assumptions:
Since state and local income taxes usually employ the same bases as the corresponding federal taxes, it is reasonable to assume that substitution of NRST for taxes at the federal level would be followed by similar substitutions at the state and local level. For simplicity I consider the economic impact of substitution at all levels simultaneously.
Boortz's rate of 23 percent (which is actually 30 percent) includes only the NRST. To this would have to be added any state or local sales tax rate. This means that in some areas of the country where the combined state and local sales taxes average 10 percent, consumers will pay a whopping 40 percent tax on all of their purchases. No wonder Jorgenson says that "as a consequence of the elimination of taxes on capital income, individuals would sharply curtail consumption of both goods and leisure."
But in Jorgenson's 1996 testimony at the "Hearings on Replacing the Federal Income Tax" held by the House Committee on Ways and Means he said that "the consumption tax rate required for replacing existing revenues from individual and corporate income taxes at both federal and state and local levels would be around fifteen percent. This would gradually rise over time reaching twenty-one."
The initial "revenue neutral" tax rate has already gone up twice and the FairTax hasn't even been implemented yet.
Other economists believe that the rate of a NRST would have to be much higher than 30 percent to be truly revenue neutral. This has been pointed out several times by Bruce Bartlett, and most recently by William Gale, an economist with the Brookings Institute, in his May 16, 2005, article " The National Retail Sales Tax: What Would the Rate Have To Be?"
Gale estimates that "a federal sales tax that maintains real federal revenues under current law and real federal noninterest spending over the 10-year period of 2006 to 2015 would require a tax-inclusive rate of 31 percent, or a tax-exclusive rate of 44 percent." This latter rate would actually climb to 49 percent by 2015. And these rates are assuming that there is no tax evasion or legislative erosion of the tax base.
Boortz's Second Misrepresentation
Boortz's second misrepresentation concerns the amount that prices could fall once the cost of embedded taxes is removed from goods. He maintains that the price of consumer goods will fall by roughly the same amount of sales tax that will be added under the FairTax plan. But again, here is Jorgenson:
Since producers would no longer pay taxes on profits or other forms of capital income under the NRST and workers would no longer pay taxes on wages, prices received by producers, shown in the sixth chart, would fall by an average of twenty percent.
In the long run producers' prices, shown in the eighth chart, would fall by almost thirty percent under the NRST.
He is saying that producers' prices will fall by about 20 percent in the short term and about 30 percent in the long term. Producer prices are not consumer prices. That is why the government has a Producer Price Index (PPI) and a Consumer Price Index (CPI). So, in order for a price increase from a national sales tax and a price decrease from the removal of the cost of embedded taxes to balance each other out, a much higher tax rate will be required since it is not consumer prices that will be 20 percent lower.
There are, of course, three other problems with any talk of a decrease in producer or consumer prices.
First, how does Jorgenson know for sure that producer prices "would fall by an average of twenty percent"? Why, an economic model that he created says they will, that's how.
And even if producer prices did fall by about 20 percent, we still have the same problem: How does anyone know for sure how much consumer prices will fall? There is one thing we know and one thing we don't know. We know that consumer prices will increase by 30 percent under the FairTax plan; we don't know how much they will decrease because of the elimination of "embedded costs" in the price of goods.
Second, saying that because costs will fall by x amount that prices will likewise fall by x amount is a grave economic fallacy. Not only does this ignore the basic laws of supply and demand, it is based on the fallacy that the costs of inputs in the production of a good determine the price of the output they produce. As Ludwig von Mises has said about prices:
The ultimate source of the determination of prices is the value judgments of the consumers. Each individual, in buying or not buying and in selling or not selling, contributes his share to the formation of market prices. But the larger the market is, the smaller is the weight of each individual's contribution. Thus the structure of market prices appears to the individual as a datum to which he must adjust his own conduct. What is called a price is always a relationship within an integrated system which is the composite effect of human relations.
Prices are determined between extremely narrow margins; the valuations on the one hand of the marginal buyer and those of the marginal offerer who abstains from selling, and the valuations on the other hand of the marginal seller and those of the marginal potential buyer who abstains from buying.
And third, the question of tax incidence who actually bears the burden of a tax is an elusive one that economists still debate. For example, many economists would argue that although a portion of the corporate income tax may be passed forward to consumers through higher prices, the majority of the tax comes out of after-tax profits and employee wages. Boortz is assuming that the full amount of all taxes paid by businesses are embedded in the costs of the goods they sell.
And what about the prices of imported goods? They would have no reason to drop at all.
Boortz's Third Misrepresentation
Boortz's third misrepresentation concerns the reason that prices could fall once the cost of embedded taxes is removed from goods. He maintains that it is the removal of the embedded taxes in the cost of goods that will account for the price reduction of those goods. Let's revisit an earlier statement of Jorgenson:
Since producers would no longer pay taxes on profits or other forms of capital income under the NRST and workers would no longer pay taxes on wages, prices received by producers, shown in the sixth chart, would fall by an average of twenty percent.
How would workers no longer paying taxes on wages lead to a fall in prices? Workers currently have deductions from their paychecks for federal income tax, Social Security tax, and Medicare tax. Although employers remit these taxes to the federal government, the money does not come out of their profits it comes out of each employee's gross pay. Jorgenson is saying that prices will fall because of two factors, not one.
Producers costs would be lower because not only would they no longer have to pay taxes on their profits, they would no longer have to remit their employees' deductions to the federal government they would pocket them.
When Jorgenson testified on the subject of "The Economic Impact of Taxing Consumption" before the House Committee on Ways and Means in 1996, he made essentially the same statement that was quoted above from his report for Americans for Fair Taxation:
Since producers would no longer pay taxes on profits or other forms of income from capital and workers would no longer pay taxes on wages, prices received by producers, shown in the fifth chart, would fall by an average of twenty percent.
After an inquiry by a citizen [4] who was concerned that the FairTax proponents were misrepresenting his conclusions, Jorgenson made his position perfectly clear:
A more reasonable interpretation of my 1996 testimony is that workers would keep that after-tax pay; producers' prices would fall, but retail prices would be increased by the national retail sales tax. Any gains by workers and investors would be the result of increased economic efficiency.
Boortz is double counting. The portion of the worker's paycheck formerly sent to the government for taxes that will be now returned to him so he can collect "100 percent of every paycheck" is the same portion that producers will now pocket to help them lower their costs. This is because Boortz originally maintained that the embedded taxes that drive up the costs of goods and services are "in addition to the money taken out of your check in income taxes and payroll taxes." He has since changed his tune.
From his Nealz Nuze, here is Boortz on what will really happen to "100% of your paycheck":
On review, and after reading the critiques of opponents to the FairTax plan, we have concluded that there is one element of the FairTax that could have been present with more clarity in the book; the concept of embedded taxes and keeping 100% of your paycheck.
We write in The FairTax Book that the competitive pressures of the marketplace will force prices down when embedded taxes disappear from the cost of retail goods and services, and we cite 22% as the average amount of those embedded taxes. Does this 22% include the income and payroll taxes that are paid by employees? Yes, it does. So what does this mean to your paycheck after the FairTax becomes law?
When the FairTax is implemented, and when business and personal income and payroll taxes disappear, your employer is going to have to make a decision. He will either take some or the entire amount he had been withholding for federal income and payroll taxes and add it to your weekly check, or he will readjust your pay figures so that your entire paycheck will be equal to what you used to call "take home pay" before the FairTax. The employer may also decide to do a little of both. Either way, you can see that the amount of money you actually receive as pay the amount you can put into your bank account will not decrease, and may actually increase.
On a larger scale real wages will rise to the extent to which the nation's employers decide to return the embedded costs of their employee's income and payroll taxes to the employee. Likewise, the cost of the products or services produced by the employer will be reduced to the extent to which that employer retains all or a portion of those income and payroll taxes together with the other taxes on capital and labor eliminated by the FairTax.
Because of Boortz's epiphany, he had to make some significant changes in his new paperback edition of The FairTax Book. Gone is the statement on page 55 that embedded taxes which drive up the cost of goods by 22 percent are "in addition to the money taken out of your check in income taxes and payroll taxes." Here are the other changes and omissions:
First edition, page 59:
Once the FairTax takes effect, you'll be receiving 100 percent of every paycheck, with no withholding of federal income taxes, Social Security taxes, or Medicare taxes and you'll be paying just about the same price for T-shirts and other consumer goods and services that you were paying before the FairTax.
Paperback edition, page 60:
Once the FairTax takes effect, you will be in complete control of your paycheck as nothing will be withheld and your purchasing power for t-shirts and all other goods and services will be almost exactly what it was before the FairTax.
First edition, page 120:
When we all start getting 100 percent of our earned income in our paychecks.
Paperback edition, page 120:
When we all start controlling 100 percent of our earned income in our paychecks.
Being in "complete control" of your paycheck no longer means keeping 100 percent of it.
First edition, page 83:
Remember that the poor, along with everyone else will no longer have Social Security taxes or Medicare taxes removed from their paychecks. Whatever they earn, they get on payday. For most of those we categorize as poor, this would mean an immediate 25 to 30 percent increase in their take-home pay.
Paperback edition, page 83:
Remember that the poor, along with everyone else will no longer have Social Security taxes or Medicare taxes removed from their paychecks. Whatever they earn, they get on payday. If employers leave this money in paychecks instead of taking it out of price, most of those we categorize as poor would see an immediate 25 to 30 percent increase in their take-home pay.
Now the increase in take-home pay is tied to the generosity of the employer. Prices cannot be reduced and take-home pay increased at the same time.
First edition, page 84:
When you factor in the lower prices caused by the disappearance of the embedded taxes, you'll see that the total price paid for consumer goods will remain very nearly the same.
Paperback edition, page 84:
When you factor in the combined lower prices/higher take-home pay caused by the disappearance of the embedded taxes, you'll see that the total price paid for consumer goods will remain very nearly the same.
This again shows that the fall in prices that may result under the FairTax is due to two factors, not just the removal of the embedded taxes.
In the "Time for a Quick Review" chart on page 111 of both editions, there are some substantial alterations:
First edition:
We start collecting 100 percent of our earnings in every paycheck.
Paperback edition:
We start controlling our earnings in every paycheck.
First edition:
We all get virtual raises, since payroll taxes are no longer siphoned from our checks.
Paperback edition: [this sentence is completely eliminated]
First edition:
The prices of consumer goods and services remain essentially the same, with the removal of the embedded taxes compensating for the added consumption tax.
Paperback edition:
Our purchasing power for buying consumer goods and services remains essentially the same, with the removal of the embedded taxes compensating for the added consumption tax.
Do these corrections mean that Boortz is no longer guilty of misrepresenting Jorgenson? Perhaps. But consider the following:
* The new edition of Boortz's book still states (on pp. 84 & 160) that people will take home 100 percent of their paycheck under the FairTax.
* The website of Boortz's coauthor, Congressman John Linder, still maintains that one of the results of the FairTax is that it "allows you to keep 100 percent of your paycheck, pension, and Social Security payments."
* The Americans for Fair Taxation website still claims that the FairTax "enables workers to keep their entire paycheck."
Boortz is very naïve to think that once the FairTax plan is implemented that employers will be able to lower employee wages just because the net amount an employee receives might be more than his current take-home pay. Not only will workers be extremely reluctant to take a pay cut, wage contracts will in many cases prevent an adjustment downward.
And consider the case of two workers who currently make the same gross pay but each with a different take-home amount because they claim a different number of exemptions. Under the FairTax plan, if wages are lowered to current take-home amounts, one employee would end up making less than the other and certainly cry foul. Can you imagine the number of workers who will, on the eve of the implementation of the FairTax, rush to change the number of their exemptions on their W-4 forms so as to increase their take-home pay before their employer has a chance to take it away?
Boortz's Fourth Misrepresentation
Boortz's fourth misrepresentation concerns Jorgenson himself. Although Boortz quotes Jorgenson to give weight to his FairTax proposal, Jorgenson is not a devotee of the FairTax he supports an income tax plan called the Efficient Taxation of Income. That's right an income tax. That means an IRS and a 1040 form, not a sales tax.
In his 1996 article, "The Economic Impact of Fundamental Tax Reform," [5] Jorgenson states: "Changing the federal tax base from income to consumption is an idea whose time has come. This change will create important new opportunities for growth in the standard of living of all Americans." But that was 1996, long before Boortz wrote his FairTax book. Since then Jorgenson has written quite extensively about his income tax plan. Here are just three examples.
In his 2002 article for the Financial Times, Jorgenson called his Efficient Taxation of Income plan "A Smarter Type of Tax," and explained that
Efficient Taxation of Income is a new approach to tax reform that would introduce different tax rates for property-type income and earned income from work. Earned income would be taxed at a flat rate of 10 per cent, while property-type income would be taxed at 30 per cent.
Also in 2002, Jorgenson testified yet again before the House Committee on Ways and Means on the subject of taxes. But instead of advocating a consumption tax like the FairTax, he presented his Efficient Taxation of Incomeproposal. Under Jorgenson's plan: "Income would be defined in exactly the same way as in the existing tax code."
In 2003, Jorgenson wrote an article for Harvard Magazine on the subject of you guessed it the Efficient Taxation of Income:
Efficient Taxation of Income is a new approach to tax reform based on taxation of income rather than consumption. This would avoid a drastic shift in tax burdens by introducing different tax rates for property-type income and earned income from work. Earned income would be taxed at a flat rate of 10 percent, while property-type income would be taxed at 30 percent.
The Fraudulent Tax
Besides the misrepresentations of Professor Jorgenson, there are other reasons the FairTax should be called the Fraudulent Tax.
The FairTax does not abolish the IRS. Changing the name and some of the functions of the IRS does not mean that it will go away. The FairTax simply exchanges one federal agency for another. If there were no IRS or other enforcement bureau to enforce the collection of a national sales tax, then why would anyone bother paying or collecting the tax? Actually, the Fair Tax Act of 2005 sets up a "Sales Tax Bureau" in the Department of the Treasury. With a bureau comes an army of bureaucrats. And what Jorgenson said in his report on "The Economic Impact of the National Retail Sales Tax" shows that these bureaucrats will still have plenty of work to do:
Any definition of a consumption tax base will have to distinguish between consumption for personal and business purposes. On-going disputes over exclusion of home offices, business-provided automobiles, equipment, and clothing, and business-related lodging, entertainment and meals would continue to plague tax officials, the entertainment and hospitality industries, and holders of expense accounts. In short, substitution of the NRST for the existing tax system would not eliminate all the practical issues that arise from the necessity of distinguishing between business and personal activities in defining consumption.
The FairTax will abolish the IRS in the same way that it will abolish the income tax by replacing it with something else.
The FairTax is not cosponsored by Congressman Ron Paul (R-TX). Every month or so since I began writing against the FairTax I have received an e-mail insisting that Congressman Paul is a cosponsor of H.R. 25, the "Fair Tax Act of 2005." Although there are fifty-eight cosponsors of this bill, Ron Paul is not one of them. Why is it that no one bothers to mention the names of the actual cosponsors of the FairTax bill?
FairTax supporters know that it is Dr. Paul who consistently votes to lower or abolish federal taxes, spending, and regulation. His support for the FairTax bill would further their cause more than any number of cosponsors or anything Boortz could ever say or write. The Americans for Fair Taxation website lists Congressman Paul as a " supporter" of the FairTax. This is strange since Dr. Paul has not taken an official position in support or opposition to the FairTax. His priority is reducing government spending and taxes, not getting sidetracked in debates about which type of tax we should have. As he has made clear: "The real issue is total spending by government, not tax reform."
So what about these cosponsors of the FairTax bill? Are they interested in reducing total spending by government? Out of the fifty-eight cosponsors, forty-four of them voted for the Medicare Prescription Drug and Modernization Act of 2003 the largest expansion of the welfare state since the Great Society. Only six voted against it [6] (eight cosponsors were not members of Congress at the time of the vote. [7]) The sponsor of the FairTax bill, John Linder, also voted for the Medicare Act. No wonder the FairTax has to be revenue neutral now with adjustments every year! How else will the government come up with the billions of dollars it will need to pay for all these prescriptions?
The FairTax is not a voluntary tax. Calling the FairTax a voluntary tax has got to be the most ridiculous thing ever said about it. Boortz maintains in his book that "there is nothing coercive about the FairTax." In Congressman Linder's testimony before The Joint Economic Committee on "Rethinking the Tax Code," he stated: "The FairTax plan is a voluntary tax system. Every citizen becomes a voluntary taxpayer, paying as much as they choose, when they choose, by how they choose to spend."
Well, could we not also say that the current tax system is a voluntary tax system? Every citizen becomes a voluntary taxpayer, paying as much as they choose, whey they choose, by how they choose to work. Under the present system, if someone doesn't work then he doesn't pay any income tax. Sounds voluntary to me. Rather than being voluntary, the FairTax is a "permission-to-live" tax, as Murray Rothbard has described consumption taxes.
We know that retail prices will increase by 30 percent under the FairTax plan; we don't know how much prices will decrease because of the elimination of "embedded costs" in the price of goods. Because it is embedded with fraud, the FairTax plan is not the answer.
The income tax should be repealed, not replaced. The IRS should be gotten rid of, not renamed. Tax reform should reduce taxes, not be revenue neutral. Government theft of the wealth of its citizens should be abolished, not adjusted. The FairTax should be called the Fraudulent Tax.
Laurence M. Vance is a freelance writer and an adjunct instructor in accounting at Pensacola Junior College in Pensacola, FL. See his Mises.org archive. Send him mail. Comment on the blog.
Notes
[1]Congressman John Linder (R-GA) is Boortz's coauthor, but since Boortz has previous writing experience and his name appears in larger letters on the book's cover, I will refer to Boortz as the author of The FairTax Book.
[2]This report is unfortunately not available online.
[3]These reports are likewise not available online.
[4]Rob Northrup, to whom also I am indebted for bringing to my attention the new paperback edition of The FairTax Book.
[5]This appeared as chapter 11 of Frontiers of Tax Reform, edited by Michael J. Boskin (Hoover Institution Press, 1996), and was reprinted by the economics department of Harvard University as part of its Reprints in Economic Theory and Econometrics.
[6]Dan Burton (R-IN), Jeff Flake (R-AZ), Jeff Miller (R-FL), Charlie Norwood (R-GA), Mike Pence (R-IN), Thomas Tancredo (R-CO).
[7]K. Michael Conaway (R-TX), Dan Boren (D-OK), Thelma Drake (R-VA), Michael McCaul (R-TX), Ted Poe (R-TX), Michael Sodrel (R-IN), Lynn Westmoreland (R-GA), Tom Price (R-GA).
Yeah, tell that to my workers. And tell that to union workers who are under contract, or any employee under contract for that matter. It is not possible for producers to ring out all these costs. The extra money goes into the pockets of the workers, and we are immediately hit with a 15-20% rise in prices the day the fairtax take effect. Try running that through the models.
It's cute what they assume in their models (higher state taxes, lower gross wages) but never talk about in their little propaganda papers.
The central problem with the FairTax on Fed Govt consumption is NOT that it taxes itself ... that is necessary to avoid the price disparity problem ... it is the fact that taxing itself generates NO NET TAX REVENUE on a portion of the tax base that is supposed to generate positive net tax revenue!
I'm sure we'll keep hearing about how "necessary" it is for the Fed Govt to tax itself; but the silence regarding the missing net tax revenue is deafening.
Kotlikoff et al throughout the paper actually take the opposite position that wages remain the same and prices rise by the full FairTax amount. Actually, neither assumption is probably going to be correct in the long run since what will most likely occur is that prices will fall a certain amount with the elimination of the income tax and then be raised by the overall effective FairTax rate for all taxpayers combined.
IOW, this price rise will be much less that the marginal 23% FairTax rate just as the effective FairTax rate is much lower than the marginal.
The more important point, though, is not the action of prices per se, but purchasing power. As has been shown repeatedly on these threads by actual examples, for a given level of income the taxpayers purchasing power (disposable personal income) is usually greatly increased under the FairTax as opposed to the income tax.
">"Private consumers would receive lower (gross) wages under the FairTax, because producer prices fall.""That's not what the paper says overall or means. That's merely the technique of the Out-Of-Context quotation to barf up a strawman. The paper actually takes the position of wages staying the same and prices rising by the FairTax amount - which as I've just explained isn't too likely IAE.
For more information about it, check post #323.
The infamous "unelected bureaucrats raising taxes" ploy you've continually tried (unsuccessfully) to use isn't correct and never has been. They merely determine the split of tax revenue required to fund the S/S entitlement as required by S/S lawThey also would determine what the FairTax rate would be every year.
Actually, neither assumption is probably going to be correct in the long run since what will most likely occur is that prices will fall a certain amount with the elimination of the income tax and then be raised by the overall effective FairTax rate for all taxpayers combined.Prices are going to rise by the effective rate? Really...
or
Real Income must shrink (thereby devaluing the puchasing power of current income earners)
or
some combination of the two.
"They also would determine what the FairTax rate would be every year."
Nice pipe dream. You income tax lovers DO so love to warp and misstate.
HR25 neither says nor means any such thing. Any change in the overall FairTax rate would have to be done by Congress, not some "unelected bureaucrat". Your statements are, simply, incorrect.
My belief is that prices will first be reduced by some amount and after that will rise but by an amount far less than the marginal FairTax rate of 23% ti. The most they would rise would be at the overall effective FairTax rate for all taxpayers combined which would be much less than the marginal FairTax rate. IOW Kotlikoff's assumption of prices rising by the marginal rate is far too pessimistic and will not happen. In fact, prices cannot rise by that much overall and due to the effects that will show up in dynamic scoring, they won't.
Does that mean that prices will be higher than at present??? Not necessarily, but purchasing power will certainly increase for most taxpayers.
Nice pipe dream. You income tax lovers DO so love to warp and misstate. HR25 neither says nor means any such thing. Any change in the overall FairTax rate would have to be done by Congress, not some "unelected bureaucrat". Your statements are, simply, incorrect.You are kidding, right? You didn't know the FairTax rate would change every year!?!
`SEC. 101. IMPOSITION OF SALES TAX.
`(a) In General- There is hereby imposed a tax on the use or consumption in the United States of taxable property or services.
`(b) Rate-
`(1) FOR 2007- In the calendar year 2007, the rate of tax is 23 percent of the gross payments for the taxable property or service.
`(2) FOR YEARS AFTER 2007- For years after the calendar year 2007, the rate of tax is the combined Federal tax rate percentage (as defined in paragraph (3)) of the gross payments for the taxable property or service.
`(3) COMBINED FEDERAL TAX RATE PERCENTAGE- The combined Federal tax rate percentage is the sum of--
`(A) the general revenue rate (as defined in paragraph (4), and
`(B) the old-age, survivors and disability insurance rate, and
`(C) the hospital insurance rate.
`(4) GENERAL REVENUE RATE- The general revenue rate shall be 14.91 percent.
`SEC. 904. TRUST FUND REVENUE.
...
`(d) Old-Age, Survivors and Disability Insurance Rate- The old-age, survivors and disability insurance rate shall be determined by the Social Security Administration. The old-age, survivors and disability insurance rate shall be that sales tax rate which is necessary to raise the same amount of revenue that would have been raised by imposing a 12.4 percent tax on the Social Security wage base (including self-employment income) as determined in accordance with chapter 21 of the Internal Revenue Code most recently in effect prior to the enactment of this Act. The rate shall be determined using actuarially sound methodology and announced at least 6 months prior to the beginning of the Calendar year for which it applies.
`(e) Hospital Insurance Rate- The hospital insurance rate shall be determined by the Social Security Administration. The hospital insurance rate shall be that sales tax rate which is necessary to raise the same amount of revenue that would have been raised by imposing a 2.9 percent tax on the Medicare wage base (including self-employment income) as determined in accordance with chapter 21 of the Internal Revenue Code most recently in effect prior to the enactment of this Act. The rate shall be determined using actuarially sound methodology and announced at least 6 months prior to the beginning of the calendar year for which it applies.
The assumption in the Kotlikoff paper being discussed is that prices will rise by the FairTax amount. My belief is that prices will first be reduced by some amount and after that will rise but by an amount far less than the marginal FairTax rate of 23% ti. The most they would rise would be at the overall effective FairTax rate for all taxpayers combined which would be much less than the marginal FairTax rate. IOW Kotlikoff's assumption of prices rising by the marginal rate is far too pessimistic and will not happen. In fact, prices cannot rise by that much overall and due to the effects that will show up in dynamic scoring, they won't.You're not making sense [shock!]. It's obvious you didn't understand what Kotlikoff was saying.
So again, Kotlikoff proves us right: the likely outcome of implementing the FairTax is a 30% rise in consumer prices and a devaluation of held assets (through "monetary accommodation" also known as "inflation") with its attendant reduction in the purchasing power of those assets.
The key phrase is not the one you highlight, but is: "... that sales tax rate which is necessary to raise the same amount of revenue that would have been raised by imposing a 12.4 percent tax on the Social Security wage base ...". Since the wage base will increase more slowly than the total economic activity, this means that the rate so derived will actually provide the funds to match the 12.4% amount mentioned in the bill but that the proportion of that wage amount in the total 23% will actually fall from its present 27.43% to perhaps 25% (of the 23% rate) or possibly even less depending upon the increase in economic activity. This would actually free up more funds for the general revenue rate which would rise after 2007 from the 14.91% figure to, say, 15%.
That result would bring about a hue and cry from taxpayers to lower the rate from 23% (if it in fact starts at that level - which is too high). I suspect that even you and your friends would bitch to high heaven about having the rate "too high".
In other words, you've ignored the simple fact that the rate 23% (or other %), composed of the two entitlement rates that total into the overall 23%, are more likely to decrease from their current proportion of the total. That is FAR more likely that the results that you keep pushing with your nonsense "unelected bureaucrat" business. The FairTax will certainly boost economic activity - every single real economic study that has been done shows this. Pretending otherwise ignores what is obviously the truth of the matter.
"You are kidding, right? You didn't know the FairTax rate would change every year!?! "
The fact that the rates in question CHANGE is not the issue but that they are undoubtedly going to FALL rather than RISE.
The fact that the rates in question CHANGE is not the issue but that they are undoubtedly going to FALL rather than RISE.Whether it falls or rises wasn't the question. You said: "HR25 neither says nor means any such thing. Any change in the overall FairTax rate would have to be done by Congress, not some 'unelected bureaucrat.' Your statements are, simply, incorrect." But HR25 clearly states that "unelected bureaucrats" in the SSA would determine the rate every year. You were wrong. Maybe, for once, you will admit it.
Being variables, this means that any or all of the four can change whereas your evaluation of the equation insists that only two of the terms change and in a direction consistent with your own biased assumptions for which you have shown no valid economic assessment or derivation - as Kotlikoff et al do.
In fact with this many variables there are many different combinations that might arise. Your two possibilities have not begun to do more than scratch the surface of the possibilities - including that several may change with no overall different outcome. But the real point is that there are certainly other possible (and even more likely) outcomes than the two you note.
The assumptions used in the paper - as stated - are that V and Y remain unchanged and while you may not agree, the footnote on that page says that Y would in fact increase. With a given wage level and no monetary accommodation as the paper assumes, V - the velocity of money - would increase. The meaning of that is there would be increased economic activity (which is what all genuine economic studies of the FairTax have shown).
So you're welcome to your assumptions but they are probably not as "realistic" as you seem to think. I believe I'll stick with the analysis of the economist in this instance ... and I believe his analysis actually understates the effects and benefits of the FairTax if anything.
"You're not making sense [shock!]. It's obvious you didn't understand what Kotlikoff was saying."
Well, ONE of us doesn't understand the paper all right ... but it's not me.
"... taxing itself generates NO NET TAX REVENUE on a portion of the tax base that is supposed to generate positive net tax revenue ...!"
And that is the same situation as today when the government "taxing itself" generates a net of zero also merely transferring funds from one account to another. So your observation about the price disparity problem is both correct and appreciated since that is certainly the larger problem of the two.
Shuffling of funds from one account to another is something the government is quite good at and any FairTax "paid out" is certainly returned to them within a month or so with the upshot being that the revenue involved is not a material amount in the big scheme of things.
"In the Private sector this would amount to a 29.87% tax on top of the employee's full paycheck. To ensure parity with the private sector, the government must do the same. "Not so!! the government need only pay the 23% excise rate on the employees' gross wages - and the definition of "gross wages" is the same as at present.
The FairTax is certainly not "revenue short" any more than the present tax system nor does it inflate the cash needs of the government to pay workers
"Since there is NO FairTax in actual wages paid to an employee (government or otherwise) the wages are "grossed up" by the amount of the FairTax (29.87% of the wages or 23% of the wages + FairTax) and the FairTax is "withheld" by the taxable employer and remitted to the government as tax revenue. "
Your evaluation misses the point (among others) that there is NO "grossing up" (as you put it) of the 23% excise paid on gross wages of government noneducational employees. It is merely 23% of the gross wage amount. If the government employee has a gross salary of $100,000 defined as at present, the revenue generated will be $23,000 in tax (period). In fact this amount would be reduced since the $7,650 ER FICA portion would no longer be involved so that the net would be $15,350 less, in fact, some allowance for reducing the amount further by the ER FICA portion no longer paid on the government educational employees. If those employees wages represented, say, 20% of the government consumption expenditures the additional reduction allowance would be substantial.
Your analysis seems to be going in the wrong direction, if anything.
Please provide a link to each of the 2 sources you mention that you believe demonstrate your claim since 23% of gross wages of noneducational employees with government as a taxable employer is the correct figure.
Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.