Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

Skip to comments.

Design Choices for a Medicare Drug Benefit (Educate Yourself)
CBO ^ | October 2002 | CBO Health & Human Resources

Posted on 11/12/2002 5:43:19 AM PST by NittanyLion




CHAPTER

2
Design Choices for a
Medicare Drug Benefit

In designing a drug benefit for Medicare, policymakers must make four fundamental decisions:

  • How comprehensive will the coverage be?

  • Who will be eligible to enroll?

  • To what extent will the government pay enrollees' costs?

  • How and by whom will the drug program be administered?

The answers to each of those questions will have a major impact on the program's cost to the federal government and to enrollees. (This chapter and the next describe, in general, how various approaches to those choices affect costs. Specific cost estimates for particular proposals are discussed in Chapter 4.)

In addition, most of those decisions will involve trade-offs among the various goals for a Medicare prescription drug benefit. For example, features designed to encourage wide enrollment--such as extensive coverage, low deductibles and copayments, broad eligibility, and subsidies for low-income enrollees--will also make the program more expensive for the federal government (and possibly for state and local governments). But features designed to control costs--such as narrow coverage, high cost sharing by enrollees, and limited eligibility--may mean that fewer Medicare beneficiaries receive the benefits of prescription drug coverage.

Any program in which the federal government subsidizes a large share of drug costs for many enrollees will require substantial federal outlays. Medicare beneficiaries are expected to spend an average of nearly $2,500 apiece on outpatient prescription drugs in 2003. Access to better drug coverage would undoubtedly stimulate further spending. However, decisions about how to administer the drug benefit can exacerbate or alleviate the federal cost burden. Consequently, those decisions are especially important.

All of the recent proposals for a Medicare drug program would rely on private entities to administer the benefit, but there are significant differences in the functions envisioned for those entities. Opportunities exist to manage drug use and prices prudently, but pharmacy benefit managers need both the incentives and the tools to do so. The Congressional Budget Office has concluded that among the designs for a Medicare drug program proposed in the past few years, those with certain administrative features offer the greatest opportunity for constraining federal costs and total spending on outpatient prescription drugs. Although not without shortcomings, those designs have three main features: they allow benefit managers to employ the full array of tools now used to administer private-sector drug plans, they force benefit managers to compete among themselves for enrollees' business, and they make managers assume financial risk for delivering benefits.
 

The Structure of the Coverage

The single biggest determinant of the cost of a Medicare drug benefit is how the coverage is designed. Choices about the structure of the coverage include:

  • The deductible amount (whether coverage begins with the first dollar of drug spending in a given year or after the deductible amount is reached);

  • Cost-sharing rates (what share of the cost of a prescription is the responsibility of the enrollee);(1)

  • The benefit cap (the level of spending beyond which the enrollee must pay the full cost of each prescription); and

  • The catastrophic stop-loss amount (the level of spending beyond which the enrollee pays little or nothing for prescriptions).

The possible variations on those choices are numerous and could produce benefits unlike anything available in the private sector today. Of the four proposals discussed in Chapter 4, the Clinton Administration's plan and H.R. 4680 both include a capped benefit, then a "hole" (a level of spending at which there would be no drug coverage), and finally a stop-loss provision, beyond which the benefit would pay all drug costs (see Figure 3). Plans currently available through employers, by contrast, almost never include such holes in coverage. The larger the range of spending encompassed by the hole, the less costly the program would be--but also the less coverage the benefit would provide.
 

Figure 3.

Hypothetical Structure of a Medicare Prescription Drug Benefit


Source: Congressional Budget Office.


The structure of the coverage also indirectly affects the cost of the drug program through the out-of-pocket spending it requires of enrollees. Benefits with low cost-sharing rates would encourage enrollees who were newly shielded from paying the full costs of their drugs to use a greater number of--and more expensive--prescriptions. Conversely, higher cost-sharing rates would induce less new drug spending.
 

Eligibility for Enrollment

A fundamental design choice concerns whether the prescription drug benefit would be available to all Medicare beneficiaries or only some (on the basis of such criteria as income, wealth, or current drug coverage). The cost of the drug program could be reduced by limiting eligibility. However, most recent proposals for Medicare drug coverage would allow all Medicare beneficiaries to enroll, although they would provide much higher subsidies to low-income beneficiaries.

A second choice for policymakers is whether to make enrollment in the benefit voluntary and, if so, with what restrictions. A voluntary drug program that did not limit when and how often an eligible person could enroll would encourage beneficiaries to sign up only when they expected to incur high drug costs and to opt out again when they expected little need for prescription drugs. All of the proposals examined in Chapter 4 would provide a voluntary drug benefit, but they would restrict that choice by giving people only one opportunity to enroll without penalty (when they first became eligible), or by imposing a surcharge on people who delayed enrollment, to reflect the higher costs that such enrollees typically entail. (When the drug program began, however, all Medicare beneficiaries, regardless of age, would have a chance to sign up for the coverage.)

Besides those two restrictions, another way to reduce beneficiaries' incentives to enroll or drop coverage at will would be to couple the drug benefit with Part B of Medicare (Supplementary Medical Insurance). In that case, beneficiaries could choose either Part B plus drug coverage or no Part B and no drug coverage. Because Medicare currently pays 75 percent of Part B benefits, and because enrollment in Part B without penalty is restricted to a brief period after eligibility begins, virtually all Medicare beneficiaries sign up for Part B. Linking the drug benefit to enrollment in Part B would probably ensure reasonably high participation in the benefit. However, if enrollment in Part B required enrollment in the drug program and the full premium (for Part B plus drugs) rose substantially as a result, some people who would otherwise enroll in Part B might drop that coverage.
 

The Level and Structure of Federal Subsidies

Two important design choices are how much the federal government would contribute to the cost of drug coverage for Medicare beneficiaries and how such subsidies would be structured. Those design choices have consequences not only for federal costs but also for costs to state and local governments. In addition, the level of subsidy offered to enrollees would have an important effect on people's willingness to take part in the drug program.

Most of the Medicare drug benefits proposed recently in the Congress would provide some level of federal subsidy for all enrollees, but they would still require those enrollees to contribute substantially--through both cost sharing and premiums. To make drug coverage more affordable to low-income Medicare beneficiaries, most proposals would provide a higher federal subsidy for enrollees who met certain eligibility criteria.

Subsidies for All Enrollees
The higher the subsidy, the greater the number of people who would want to enroll in a drug benefit, but also the greater the costs to the federal government. Widespread enrollment is desirable for two reasons: it means that the drug benefit is accomplishing the goal of providing insurance to most Medicare beneficiaries, and it reduces the likelihood that enrollees will be drawn disproportionately from people who expect to have high drug costs. The question for policymakers is, How large would the federal subsidy have to be to induce most Medicare beneficiaries to enroll?

Even if the federal subsidy was small, enrollment would still be fairly high because many people with private or public drug coverage would probably be required to enroll. For example, employment-based health plans would probably require retirees eligible for a Medicare drug benefit to participate in it, just as they now effectively require that retirees participate in Part B. Even employers who offered to pay Medicare's drug premium for retirees would have lower costs so long as that premium was subsidized to any extent (assuming their retirees were not markedly less costly than the average Medicare participant). The more comprehensive Medicare's drug coverage was, the more employers' health care costs for retirees would be reduced, but they would probably take advantage of even a limited drug benefit. Likewise, state Medicaid agencies, even if not required to do so, would choose to enroll people eligible for both Medicare and Medicaid in a Medicare drug program if states' costs under the new program were less than under Medicaid's current drug benefit.

Thus, the people whose participation would be most sensitive to the size of the federal subsidy would be the one-quarter of Medicare beneficiaries without drug coverage from private or public sources. If the drug benefit was not subsidized and enrollment was always open, few of those beneficiaries would be likely to enroll. If, however, they had only one chance to enroll without financial penalty, some of those beneficiaries would probably take part without any federal subsidy, and most would choose to enroll at subsidy rates well below 100 percent of the cost. The reason is that virtually all beneficiaries would expect to receive more in benefits in some years than the premiums they paid. One-time-only enrollment would also increase the extent of participation for any given level of subsidy. However, a drug benefit that was financed mainly by enrollees could be difficult for some people to afford--specifically, people whose income or assets were only slightly too high to qualify for drug coverage through Medicaid or other public programs.

Subsidies for Low-Income Enrollees
Creating an additional subsidy program for low-income users of a Medicare drug benefit requires making decisions about such things as eligibility for the subsidy, the size of the subsidy, and whether states would pay a share. Those choices would affect enrollment in the drug benefit and its cost to the federal government and the states.

Who Would Be Eligible? As noted earlier, some low-income Medicare beneficiaries receive assistance for part or all of their medical costs through the federal/state Medicaid program. Those beneficiaries fall into three categories.

  • Dual eligibles meet all state requirements for Medicaid eligibility, either because their income and assets are below the limits set by a state or because they have "spent down" their resources to those limits as a result of high medical costs (in which case they are referred to as the medically needy). People in the first group have their Medicare premiums and cost sharing paid by Medicaid. They also receive all Medicaid benefits, including coverage for prescription drugs. Most medically needy beneficiaries receive the same benefits, although a few states do not cover their expenses for drugs.

  • Qualified Medicare beneficiaries (QMBs) have income below the federal poverty level and meet certain restrictions on financial assets. About 75 percent of them qualify as dual eligibles; the other 25 percent are eligible for benefits only as QMBs. That group has its Medicare premiums and cost sharing paid by Medicaid but is not eligible for other Medicaid benefits, such as drug coverage.

  • Specified low-income Medicare beneficiaries (SLMBs) have income between 100 percent and 120 percent of the federal poverty level and meet certain restrictions on financial assets. About one-third of them qualify as dual eligibles; the other two-thirds qualify only as SLMBs. The sole benefit that SLMBs receive from Medicaid is payment of their Medicare Part B premiums.

Most proposals for a Medicare drug benefit include some form of low-income subsidy for beneficiaries in all of those categories.

In addition, most recent Medicare drug proposals would assist other low-income Medicare beneficiaries. Proposals typically call for providing subsidies to all enrollees with income below 135 percent of the poverty level (and limited assets), which would cover their premiums and cost sharing for prescription drugs. Enrollees with income between 135 percent and 150 percent of the poverty level would have some or all of their premiums subsidized. Many proposals would extend the subsidies to enrollees with even higher income. (A few proposals would remove limits on assets.)

How Much Would States Pay? A key design choice for low-income subsidies is how much would be funded by the federal government and how much by the states. The federal government now pays 57 percent of Medicaid costs, on average, with the states covering the rest. Some proposals for a Medicare drug benefit would maintain the current federal percentage for dual eligibles and QMBs. However, the federal government would pay the full subsidy for other low-income enrollees (those who met special income and asset limits established for low-income subsidies in the drug program). Other proposals would require the federal government to pay the full cost of the subsidies for all low-income enrollees, including dual eligibles. In many of those cases, states would be required to reimburse the federal government for some share of the amount they saved under the proposal.

A proposal that increased the federal government's share of the cost of low-income subsidies would reduce states' costs, and vice versa. The low-income subsidy would also augment or (at the state's option) replace state-run drug programs for low-income seniors who are not eligible for Medicaid. As noted earlier, 34 states either have introduced or are planning to introduce such programs. A federal subsidy of Medicare beneficiaries in those programs would directly reduce state spending.

Who Would Participate? The cost of a low-income subsidy program would ultimately depend on how many people participated. Not all eligible Medicare beneficiaries would choose to receive a low-income subsidy even if they enrolled in the drug benefit. Some might want to avoid being associated with a government "welfare" program; others might not believe that they were eligible for or needed the subsidy.

What entity was chosen to administer the low-income subsidy program could affect the level of participation. CBO estimates that only 50 percent of people eligible for QMB subsidies and 30 percent of those eligible for SLMB subsidies take part in those programs today. Most recent proposals for a Medicare drug benefit would rely on state Medicaid agencies to determine eligibility and enroll low-income beneficiaries--as the QMB and SLMB programs do now. However, another option would be to have the Social Security Administration (SSA) provide those enrollment services. Participation would be higher under that arrangement because less "welfare" stigma is associated with SSA than with Medicaid.

As was the case with subsidies for all enrollees, the size of the low-income subsidies would also influence participation. A larger subsidy would almost certainly induce more people to take part in the low-income program.

That effect would also depend on the design of the Medicare drug coverage. High deductibles or premiums might persuade eligible low-income beneficiaries to sign up for the low-income subsidy to cover those up-front costs. Similarly, the more generous the coverage of drug expenses beyond the deductible, the stronger would be the incentive to enroll.

Perhaps the major issue affecting participation by low-income beneficiaries is whether the asset standards now in place for Medicaid would be relaxed for the Medicare drug benefit. Most proposals would retain the asset standards currently used to determine QMBs and SLMBs. However, less-stringent standards would expand the number of people eligible for low-income subsidies.

The Effect on Spending for Medicaid. Adding prescription drug coverage to Medicare would alter not only federal spending for that program but also federal and state spending for Medicaid. Such coverage would reduce Medicaid's costs for dual eligibles because Medicare would pick up part of their prescription drug costs. However, some of that reduction would be offset by higher enrollment in the Medicaid program. Some people who are now eligible for Medicaid do not enroll; a Medicare drug benefit would give them a new incentive to do so, because under most proposals, state Medicaid programs would administer the low-income subsidies. Thus, people applying for Medicare drug coverage under the low-income subsidy would learn about their eligibility for Medicaid and enroll in that program at the same time.

Other Factors Affecting the Cost of Low-Income Subsidies. The effect on federal costs for low-income subsidies would depend not just on the factors discussed above but also on the interplay between the coverage provided by a Medicare drug benefit and the provisions for low-income subsidies. In general, increasing cost sharing for enrollees in the drug benefit would lead to higher federal subsidies for low-income enrollees. Conversely, reducing enrollees' cost sharing would result in lower federal costs for low-income subsidies.
 

Administrative Approach

The way in which a Medicare drug program was administered could also have a significant impact on its cost. Most recent proposals envision the approach--now common in the private sector--of using organizations such as pharmacy benefit managers (PBMs) to administer the benefit. The proposals differ, however, in the number of such organizations that would serve a region, the restrictions they would be subject to, the basis on which they could compete for enrollees, and whether they would assume any insurance risk. (Insurance risk occurs when the entity providing coverage is liable for payments that may not be fully covered by premiums or reimbursements or, conversely, is allowed to keep part of surpluses when costs fall short of premiums or reimbursements.)

In the past decade, PBMs have come to play a central role in administering prescription drug benefits in the private sector (see Figure 4). Their main function is to act as a health plan's agent in administering a drug benefit. PBMs do not distribute prescription drugs to patients, except when they own mail-order or community pharmacies. Instead, prescription drugs flow from manufacturers to dispensing pharmacies (often with stops along the way at wholesalers' warehouses) and then to consumers, either at pharmacies or by mail. A pharmacy pays a manufacturer for the drugs it purchases and in turn charges a price it has negotiated with the PBM. The consumer and health plan share the responsibility for paying that price.
 

Figure 4.

The Role of PBMs in the Flow of Money and Prescription Drugs


Source: Congressional Budget Office.

Note: PBM = pharmacy benefit manager.


PBMs perform various functions and use various management tools. They process and pay claims. On behalf of a health plan and its enrollees, they also negotiate price discounts with dispensing pharmacies and rebates with drug manufacturers. In return for receiving rebates, PBMs try to steer enrollees toward preferred or formulary drugs. (A formulary is a list of drugs that the health plan will cover. Nonpreferred drugs are covered and therefore included in the formulary, but they typically entail higher cost sharing for the enrollee than preferred drugs do.) PBMs' other strategies for lowering costs include encouraging the use of generic drugs and dispensing drugs through mail-order pharmacies, which many large PBMs own. PBMs may establish and enforce differential cost-sharing requirements to encourage enrollees to select lower-cost drugs. In addition, because they keep centralized records of each enrollee's prescriptions, they can help prevent inappropriate dosages and harmful drug interactions.(2)

Although PBMs in the private sector often have considerable leeway in the tools they can use, they do not assume any insurance risk for the drug benefits they administer. However, they may have a bonus added to, or a penalty subtracted from, their administrative fee on the basis of how well they meet preset goals for their performance.

Some of the Medicare drug proposals developed during the 106th Congress, such as the Clinton Administration's, called for a single PBM selected periodically to serve each region, with all insurance risk borne by Medicare, not the PBM. Other proposals, such as H.R. 4680, adopted a different approach: they would use multiple risk-bearing entities (such as PBM/insurer partnerships) that would compete to serve enrollees in each region. Enrollees would have some choice among entities, so people who were willing to accept more restrictive rules (such as a limited formulary) in return for lower cost sharing or premiums could do so, while others could select a more expensive plan with fewer restrictions. Hybrid models have been proposed in which multiple entities would compete for enrollees without bearing insurance risk. They could compete on the basis of such features as lower drug prices, fewer limits on covered drugs, and wider networks of pharmacies.

Each administrative model has its pros and cons. The next chapter describes how each model addresses key problems inherent in designing a Medicare prescription drug program--such as the risk to plans from enrolling a disproportionately large share of people with high expected drug costs, the need to control drug spending, and the feasibility of administering the benefit efficiently.




1.  Cost-sharing rates can be specified as dollar amounts (copayments) or as a percentage of costs (coinsurance).

2.  See, for example, E.P. Armstrong and C.R. Denemark, "How Pharmacists Respond to On-Line, Real-Time DUR Alerts," Journal of the American Pharmaceutical Association, vol. 38, no. 2 (March-April 1998), pp. 149-154; and Stephen Soumerai and Helene Lipton, "Computer-Based Drug-Utilization Review," New England Journal of Medicine, vol. 332, no. 24 (June 15, 1995), pp. 1641-1645.


Previous Page Table of Contents Next Page


Home Page



TOPICS: Business/Economy; Extended News; Government; News/Current Events; Politics/Elections
KEYWORDS: benefit; medicare; prescription; socializedmedicine
Navigation: use the links below to view more comments.
first 1-2021 next last
I know this is a bit long, but now that it appears a Medicare Drug benefit is a certainty it may be a good idea to educate ourselves on the various alternatives.

The article's hyperlinks do not work (and I don't have time to go through and edit them all). If you'd like to read the entire article please click on the source link at top. Thanks.

1 posted on 11/12/2002 5:43:19 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | View Replies]

Bush and G.O.P. to Push for Medicare Drug Benefit
2 posted on 11/12/2002 5:50:13 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion
This is NOT a good thing. Medicare and Medicaid cost TEN TIMES what it was originally proposed to cost. This prescription-drug transfer payment will no different.
3 posted on 11/12/2002 5:56:36 AM PST by Orangedog
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: Orangedog
This is NOT a good thing. Medicare and Medicaid cost TEN TIMES what it was originally proposed to cost. This prescription-drug transfer payment will no different.

The GOP proposal would apparently cost $370 billion. Given what we know about past programs' intended scope vs. their actual scope, we should certainly worry about a vastly expanded program somewhere down the line.

Incidentally (IMHO), this program will do very little to attract the votes of senior citizens. Democrats propose a plan far larger in scope (and cost) than this one. Seniors want more money spent on this program; Democrats will cast the GOP as far too stingy and will still retain those votes.

4 posted on 11/12/2002 6:05:04 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 3 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion
In order to get the drug companies on board, there will be arm twisting to encourage price caps (maximum allowable charges) with agreement to accept assignment--just like the current government payers. Any sort of program will result in cost shifting to non-government payers (whether commercial or self-pay).

Prescription drug costs (and health care costs in general) have skyrocketed with commercial insurance co-pays of $10-$20.

As long as people have insurance, few will notice or care about the actual costs. It's very similar to employee withholding taxes, versus writing the income tax check with your own pen.

Moreover, costs to process the prescriptions will increase enormously as pharmacies, drug companies contend with the government regulations. < /rant>

5 posted on 11/12/2002 6:12:35 AM PST by NautiNurse
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: NautiNurse
In order to get the drug companies on board, there will be arm twisting to encourage price caps (maximum allowable charges) with agreement to accept assignment--just like the current government payers. Any sort of program will result in cost shifting to non-government payers (whether commercial or self-pay).

Absolutely. A hidden cost that only the most astute observers will notice.

I was surprised to see the pharma sector up in yesterday's trading (perhaps it's mostly defensive buying as money flees other sectors). A Medicare drug benefit will likely devastate the industry - between price caps and a shift to generics the big pharma companies will be hurt.

6 posted on 11/12/2002 6:18:23 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 5 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion
Insurance of all shapes and styles have been the culprits for the health care industry's out of sight insane costs.

Adding another layer of bureaucracy to the drug mix will add to the mess. History speaks for itself--as dental insurance broke into the fray, dental fees broke through the rooftops.

p.s. Keep an eye out for veterinary insurance and watch your animal care costs rise as it is growing too.

7 posted on 11/12/2002 6:33:16 AM PST by NautiNurse
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 6 | View Replies]

To: Miss Marple
This article's a long one, but it provides some additional info on various Medicare drug benefits. Thought you might be interested...
8 posted on 11/12/2002 7:43:46 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 7 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion
Thank you. I share your concern about escalating costs. On the other hand, I just picked up a new antibiotic that cost $179. I have insurance, but I was still dumbfounded. A senior would not be able to make that payment if they were on a lower fixed income, and there is no generic yet available.

There are people who can't pay for medicine, although the Republican plan indicates there are not as many as the democrats would like the public to believe.

As I said, since we are stuck with Medicare, I don't have a problem helping low-income people get medicine, especially if it keeps them from having more expensive procedures, which Medicare would pay for anyway.

9 posted on 11/12/2002 7:49:37 AM PST by Miss Marple
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 8 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion
           
Table 5.
Provisions of Four Prescription Drug Proposals for Medicare

  Clinton
Mid-Session
Review Plan
Robb
Amendment
H.R. 4680 Breaux-
Frist II

Benefit Amounts (Dollars)a
  Deductible None 250 250 250
  Benefit cap 1,000 None 1,050 1,050
  Stop-loss amount 4,000 4,000 6,000 6,000
Benefit Administrator SSA SSA Plans SSA
Subsidies for Employment-Based Health Plans Yes Yes Nob Nob
Number of Plans in Each Region One At least two At least two At least two
Plans Bear Insurance Risk No No Yes Yes
Federal Subsidy for All Enrolleesc 50% subsidy of
premium costs
below stop-loss amount; 100% above
50% subsidy of
premium costs
No subsidy of
premium costs;
graduated
reinsurance rate,
averaging 35%d
25% subsidy of
premium costs
below stop-loss amount; 80%
reinsurance above

Source: Congressional Budget Office.
Note: SSA = Social Security Administration. [For a graphical presentation of the structure of the four proposed benefits, click here.]
a. The amounts that would apply in the Medicare drug benefit's first year of operation, which is assumed to be calendar year 2005.

10 posted on 11/12/2002 7:55:06 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion
                     
Table 6.
CBO's Assumptions for Four Prescription Drug Proposals

  Clinton
Mid-Session
Review Plan
Robb
Amend-
ment
H.R.
4680
Breaux-
Frist II

Values for Calendar Years 2005 Through 2012
Percentage of Medicare Part B Enrollees Who Would Participate in the Drug Benefit  
  Direct participation 86   85   75   87  
  Indirect participation (Through employer subsidy) 7   7   a   a  
Percentage of Medicare Part B Enrollees Who Would Not Participate in the Drug Benefit  
  People with other drug coverageb 7   7   7   5  
  People without other drug coverage 0   0   18   8  
    Total (All Medicare Part B Enrollees) 100   100   100   100  
Cost-Management Factorc (Percent) 10   17.5   30   30  
Federal Subsidy of Benefit Costs and Administrative Expenses for Enrollees in the Medicare Drug Program (Percent) 76   50   32   43  
Share of Total Drug Spending by or for Medicare Beneficiaries Paid by the Federal Government (Percent) 29   21   12   15  
Values for Calendar Year 2005
Enrollees' Share of Monthly Premium (Dollars) 30   67   72   56  
Plans' Marketing and Enrollment Costs (As a percentage of benefit spending) 0   7.8   13.5   11.9  
Risk Premiumd (As a percentage of benefit spending) 0   0   4.6   5.0  
Percentage Increase in Drug Prices Expected Because of New Benefite 0.9   1.5   *   0.1  
Percentage of Benefit Costs Resulting from Increased Demand for Drugs Under New Benefitf 7.6   8.9   4.4   5.1  
Values for Calendar Year 2012
Enrollees' Share of Monthly Premium (Dollars) 71   137   119   95  
Plans' Marketing and Enrollment Costs (As a percentage of benefit spending) 0   2.4   4.6   4.1  
Risk Premiumd (As a percentage of benefit spending) 0   0   3.3   3.6  
Percentage Increase in Drug Prices Expected Because of New Benefite 6.8   11.8   0.2   0.5  
Percentage of Benefit Costs Resulting from Increased Demand for Drugs Under New Benefitf 9.6   8.7   3.9   4.7  

Source: Congressional Budget Office.
Note: * = less than 0.05 percent.

11 posted on 11/12/2002 7:56:36 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 10 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion
                     
Table 7.
Federal Costs of Four Prescription Drug Proposals, 2005-2012

(By fiscal year, in billions of dollars)
  Clinton
Mid-Session
Review Plan
Robb
Amendment
H.R. 4680 Breaux-
Frist II

Federal Mandatory Spending on Prescription Drug Benefits for Medicare Beneficiaries  
  Medicare 507   342   120   178  
  Other federal programsa -145   -142   -84   -78  
  Low-income subsidy 128   148   141   123  
Other Mandatory Spending 22   27   18   10  
    Total 512   374   195   233  

Source: Congressional Budget Office.
Note: These numbers exclude a small amount of appropriated funds for federal administrative costs.
a. Principally Medicaid, the Federal Employees Health Benefits program, and the military's Tricare for Life program. Negative numbers indicate savings.


12 posted on 11/12/2002 7:57:11 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 11 | View Replies]

To: Orangedog
You are absolutely right that this is not a good thing. It is also, of course, well outside anything envisioned in the Constitution.

For the insane economics of Federal involvement in Medicine, see Medicare--Panacea or Death Potion?. This program dooms us to perpetual deficits and economic inbalances that will effect far more interests than any of the proponents dare acknowledge.

William Flax Return Of The Gods Web Site

13 posted on 11/12/2002 8:08:46 AM PST by Ohioan
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 3 | View Replies]

To: Miss Marple
Good point about the generic equivalents. Extending drug patents over and over beyond their normal expiration has been another factor in sky high prescription costs.
14 posted on 11/12/2002 8:21:59 AM PST by NautiNurse
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 9 | View Replies]

To: Miss Marple
"I just picked up a new antibiotic that cost $179"

But wouldn't you be asking (actually, telling) me to pay for it instead of you? I can't afford it. You see, I'm already paying for just about all the other medical care for seniors and the poor. And I'm paying for my own and my family.

Keep in mind, it's the prescription drug coverage that is pushing Canadian health care over the brink.

15 posted on 11/12/2002 8:50:29 AM PST by robertpaulsen
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 9 | View Replies]

To: Miss Marple
On the other hand, I just picked up a new antibiotic that cost $179.

I truly believe much of that cost is driven by government interference in the R&D and approval process. So much capital and time is needed to bring a drug to market that the costs seem exorbitant.

16 posted on 11/12/2002 8:55:29 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 9 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion
Incidentally (IMHO), this program will do very little to attract the votes of senior citizens. Democrats propose a plan far larger in scope (and cost) than this one. Seniors want more money spent on this program; Democrats will cast the GOP as far too stingy and will still retain those votes.

The dems will get their plan either way. The Republican's plan will open the door and the dems will institute the rest of their plan little by little, just like they have with gun control and the way they are systematically putting more and more of the middle class on welfare with crap like the (un)earned income tax credit, child day care transfer payments, and SSI checks to women with kids drugged up on ritalin. Basically, if you're single, work for a living and don't produce a gaggle of kids that you couldn't afford to support in the first place, you get to pick up the tab.

17 posted on 11/12/2002 10:26:51 AM PST by Orangedog
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 4 | View Replies]

To: *Socialized Medicine
http://www.freerepublic.com/perl/bump-list
18 posted on 11/12/2002 10:46:02 AM PST by Free the USA
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 17 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion; Miss Marple
With an antibiotic costing $179, I certainly hope a culture and sensivity of the infection was done to determine whether that drug was truly necessary. I would have insisted on it.

Overuse of antibiotics unnecessarily has resulted in bacterial resistance to much more cost effective antibiotics. Physicians have been writing prescriptions for years in an effort to placate patients with viral illnesses that do not respond to antibiotics. In many cases a placebo would have been better in the long run.

19 posted on 11/12/2002 11:05:36 AM PST by NautiNurse
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 16 | View Replies]

To: NittanyLion
BTTT.
20 posted on 11/14/2002 5:49:49 AM PST by NittanyLion
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]


Navigation: use the links below to view more comments.
first 1-2021 next last

Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.

Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

FreeRepublic, LLC, PO BOX 9771, FRESNO, CA 93794
FreeRepublic.com is powered by software copyright 2000-2008 John Robinson