Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

To: Uncle Bill
Transaction-cost augmentation was central to approval of this withholding measure. It was packaged with an omnibus tax bill, increasing the transaction costs to legislators and voters of resisting the provision. Despite repeated congressional efforts to allow a separate vote on the issue, the House of Representatives did not vote separately on the withholding section of TEFRA.[f18] Moreover, contrary to article 1, section 7 of the Constitution, the bill's substantive provisions (including the withholding measure) did not originate in the House of Representatives at all but rather in the Senate Finance Committee. The Senate bill was tacked on to a minor House bill, and the package was sent to conference without House hearings or debate on the bill. The conference bill then returned to the House under a closed rule which precluded amendment or separate voting on its individual provisions. Through procedures described on the House floor as having ``abrogated our constitutional responsibilities,'' the omnibus budget bill strategy permitted the withholding provision to become law despite a House vote two years earlier rejecting 404-4 the study of withholding on dividends and interest (U.S. Cong. Rec.-House, 19 August 1982: 22219). Ex ante, many in Congress considered tax enforcement through withholding to be less painful than new taxes as a way to narrow the budget deficit.

However, the new withholding provision was not less painful in practice. Public opposition was profound. By August 5, 1983, one month after withholding was to have taken effect under TEFRA, the Interest and Dividend Tax Compliance Act of 1983 (P.L. 98-67, 97 Stat. 369, 5 August 1983) repealed TEFRA's provision for withholding on interest and dividends. In its place Congress authorized expanded information reporting coupled with ``backup withholding'' of 20 percent in specific circumstances involving taxpayer noncompliance.

The repeal of the TEFRA withholding provision reflects the internal dynamics of determinants of transaction-cost augmentation. While variables discussed above impelled congressmen toward use of transaction-cost-increasing strategies to pass TEFRA, many misjudged the intensity of constituent hostility to the withholding provision. But perhaps the measure served its political purpose nonetheless. Since tax compliance provisions accounted for 21 percent of the additional revenue claimed to be generated by TEFRA, the evanescent authorization of interest and dividend withholding allowed Congress the political benefit without the political cost of claimed budget deficit reduction (U.S. House Report No. 98-120, 1983: 2).

Finally, the 1983 repeal of withholding on interest and dividends provides suggestive evidence regarding the long-term influence of transaction-cost augmentation and the path dependency of institutional change. Absent 40 years' experience of withholding, public opinion in 1983 might have opposed wage and salary withholding with equal intensity.[f19]

Entrenchment of the Machinery of Government

It is now a minimal problem to maintain a withholding system on salaries and wages, which is absolutely at the heart of our self-assessment technique of paying taxes.

--G. William Miller, Secretary of the Treasury
(U.S. House Hearings 1980: 23-24)

The question is, can such long-established and carefully contrived practices be reversed--and, more relevantly, are they likely to be reversed? In a representative democracy, the answer to the first question is unequivocally affirmative. Nonetheless, if the theory and evidence presented here are substantially accurate, the answer to the second question is unequivocally negative. The essence of transaction-cost augmentation is guided deflection of certain types of collective political action in order to facilitate establishment and continuation of policies often initially inconsistent with people's preferences. We have seen that the long-run result of such institutional change is authority-legitimating ideological change that renders policy reversal increasingly unlikely.

One sobering result of the present study is its evidence of key public officials' extensive awareness of the dynamics of transaction-cost manipulation. As their published statements made clear, many officeholders deliberately sought the transaction-cost-increasing results of their income tax withholding policies. Along with the public, other officeholders--such as those in 1943 who did not understand the present-value issue--were targets of those transaction-cost-manipulating strategies.

The history of U.S. income tax withholding documented here is consistent with the theory discussed earlier in this article. We have seen that, on many levels, income tax withholding increases transaction costs to the public of understanding the magnitude of the income tax and of opposing it politically. Government officials always have regarded withholding as a seemingly ``painless alternative'' (U.S. House Hearings 1980: 35). Lacking an understanding of the concept of present value, many taxpayers do not perceive that withholding causes the real burden of their tax liability to be greater. Indeed, the common practice of overwithholding associates the payment of taxes with an apparent financial benefit rather than cost, distorting taxpayers' assessments of the actual costs and benefits of government activity. Consistent with a transaction-cost-manipulation model, the expected return of such overpayments makes people feel ``happier'' about sending in their tax returns on April 15. The very mechanism of withholding deflects blame from the government by requiring employers to initiate and bear the cost of the forcible extraction of people's income. Piecemeal collection each payday from income the taxpayer never sees obscures the magnitude of the annual tax. And, because it is a forcible extraction, it raises the transaction costs to the public of expressing political resistance to taxes by not paying them.

In examining the process of passing the Current Tax Payment Act of 1943, we have seen that key variables identified by the theory as determinants of transaction-cost augmentation played their expected roles. The complexity of the withholding measure, the appealing rationale provided by wartime revenue needs, executive support, constituent support induced by purported tax forgiveness, ideologies shaped by the already expanded role of government, and lack of media publicity regarding the measure's transaction-cost-increasing features all contributed as expected to adoption of the Act. Consistent with the theory, the history of income tax withholding showed institutional experiences born of transaction-cost manipulation in turn influencing predominant public ideologies, thereby building long-run support for expanded government authority buttressed by additional transaction-cost-increasing institutions.

After 50 years of comprehensive withholding at the source of American workers' salaries, people are used to wage withholding; most no longer question it. The relevant institutional machinery is entrenched, both through its administrative apparatus and through its acceptance in the minds of most taxpayers. Some resistance does remain. Representative Bill Gradison (R., Ohio), for instance, stated (U.S. House Hearings 1980: 46) that ``one of the greatest steps we can take toward holding down expenditures and making people aware of the cost to Government would be to reexamine our assumption that wages must be withheld upon.'' More recently (Wall Street Journal 1994), in conjunction with his proposal to replace the existing income tax with a flat tax, Representative Dick Armey (R., Texas) recommended elimination of withholding, calling it a ``crucial, deceptive device'' that has allowed government ``to raise taxes to their current level without igniting a rebellion.'' But such voices are few. As ideologies accommodate altered institutional reality, as citizens' views about what ought to be come more nearly to reflect what is, government manipulation of political transaction costs provides one key part of the explanation of how such politico-economic change has occurred.


References

Armey, D. (1994) ``Review Merits of Flat Tax.'' Wall Street Journal, 16 June: A18.

Baack, B.D., and Ray, E.J. (1985a) ``Special Interests and the Adoption of the Income Tax in the United States.'' The Journal of Economic History 45(3): 607-25.

Baack, B.D., and Ray, E.J. (1985b) ``The Political Economy of the Origin and Development of the Federal Income Tax.'' In Higgs, R. (ed.) Emergence of the Modern Political Economy, Research in Economic History, Supp. 4, 121-38. Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press.

Bopeley, J.L. (1943) ``Pay-As-You-Go, Civil War Style.'' Taxes 21(7): 376-77, 408.

Brinkley, D. (1988) Washington Goes to War. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.

Buenker, J.D. (1981) ``The Ratification of the Federal Income Tax Amendment.'' Cato Journal 1(1): 183-223.

Cantril, H. (1951) Public Opinion 1935-1946. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

Doernberg, R.L. (1982) ``The Case Against Withholding.'' Texas Law Review 61(4): 595-653.

Ekirch, A.A. Jr. (1981) ``The Sixteenth Amendment: The Historical Background.'' Cato Journal 1(1): 161-82.

Forsythe, D.W. (1977) Taxation and Political Change in the Young Nation, 1781-1833. New York: Columbia University Press.

Gallup, G.H. (1972) The Gallup Poll: Public Opinion 1935-1971, Vol. 1. New York: Random House.

Higgs, R. (1985) ``Crisis, Bigger Government, and Ideological Change: Two Hypotheses on the Ratchet Phenomenon.'' Explorations in Economic History 22: 1-28.

Higgs, R. (1987) Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government. New York: Oxford University Press.

Higgs, R. (1988) ``Can the Constitution Protect Private Rights during National Emergencies?'' In Gwartney, J.D., and Wagner, R.E. (eds.) Public Choice and Constitutional Economics, 369-86. Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press.

Jones, C.C. (1989) ``Class Tax to Mass Tax: The Role of Propaganda in the Expansion of the Income Tax during World War II.'' Buffalo Law Review 37(3): 685-737.

Kuran, T. (1987) ``Preference Falsification, Policy Continuity and Collective Conservatism.'' Economic Journal 97: 642-65.

Kuran, T. (1991) ``Cognitive Limitations and Preference Evolution.'' Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 147: 241-73.

Kuran, T. (1993) ``The Unthinkable and the Unthought.'' Rationality and Society 5(4): 473-505.

Leff, M.H. (1983) ``Taxing the `Forgotten Man': The Politics of Social Security Finance in the New Deal.'' The Journal of American History 70(2): 359-81.

Leff, M.H. (1984) The Limits of Symbolic Reform: The New Deal and Taxation, 1933-1939. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Lent, G.E. (1942) ``Collection of the Personal Income Tax at the Source.'' Journal of Political Economy 50(5): 719-37.

Paul, R.E. (1943) ``The Impact of Taxation on Consumer Spending.'' Taxes 21(2): 325-28, 351.

Twight, C. (1983) Government Manipulation of Constitutional-Level Transaction Costs: An Economic Theory and Its Application to Off-Budget Expenditure through the Federal Financing Bank. Doctoral dissertation. Seattle: University of Washington.

Twight, C. (1988) ``Government Manipulation of Constitutional-Level Transaction Costs: A General Theory of Transaction-Cost Augmentation and the Growth of Government.'' Public Choice 56: 131-52.

Twight, C. (1989) ``Institutional Underpinnings of Parochialism: The Case of Military Base Closures.'' Cato Journal 9(1): 73-105.

Twight, C. (1991) ``From Claiming Credit to Avoiding Blame: The Evolution of Congressional Strategy for Asbestos Management.'' Journal of Public Policy 11(2): 153-86.

Twight, C. (1992) ``Constitutional Renegotiation: Impediments to Consensual Revision.'' Constitutional Political Economy 3: 89-112.

Twight, C. (1993) ``Channeling Ideological Change: The Political Economy of Dependence on Government.'' Kyklos 46(4): 497-527.

Twight, C. (1994) ``Political Transaction-Cost Manipulation: An Integrating Theory.'' Journal of Theoretical Politics 6(2): 189-216.

U.S. Congress (1943) Congressional Record, Vol. 89.

U.S. Congress (1982) Congressional Record, Vol. 128.

U.S. Congress (1983) Congressional Record, Vol. 129.

U.S. House of Representatives (23 January 1871) Comm. on Ways and Means, ``Income Tax: Letter from the Commissioner of Internal Revenue.'' House Mis. Doc. No. 51, 41-3.

U.S. House of Representatives (April-May 1941) Comm. on Ways and Means, Revenue Revision of 1941. Hearings, Vol. 1, 77-1.

U.S. House of Representatives (March-April 1942) Comm. on Ways and Means, Revenue Revision of 1942. Hearings [on H.R. 7378], Revised, Vols. 1-2, 77-2.

U.S. House of Representatives (February 1943) Comm. on Ways and Means, Individual Income Tax. Hearings [On a Proposal to Place Income Tax of Individuals on a Pay-As-You-Go Basis], 78-1.

U.S. House of Representatives (28 May 1943) Current Tax Payment Act of 1943. Conference Report [To accompany H.R. 2570], House Report No. 510, 78-1.

U.S. House of Representatives (October 1979) Comm. on Ways and Means, Underground Economy. Hearings, Serial 96-70, 96-1.

U.S. House of Representatives (30 April-1 May 1980) Comm. on Ways and Means, President's Proposal for Withholding on Interest and Dividends. Hearings, Serial 96-92, 96-2.

U.S. House of Representatives (19 March 1982) Comm. on the Budget, User Fees and Withholding Taxes on Interest and Dividends. Hearing, 97-2.

U.S. House of Representatives (18 May 1982) Comm. on Ways and Means, Tax Compliance Act of 1982 and Related Legislation. Hearing [On H.R. 6300], Serial 97-63, 97-2.

U.S. House of Representatives (13 May 1983) Comm. on Ways and Means. House Report No. 98-120 [To accompany H.R. 2973].

U.S. Senate (19 July 1894) Estimate of the Probable or Possible Revenue under the Proposed Income Tax. Senate Mis. Doc. No. 232, 53-1.

U.S. Senate (16 June 1909) ``Tax on Net Income of Corporations.'' Message from the President of the United States, Senate Doc. No. 98, 61-1.

U.S. Senate (16 February 1910) ``Message from the Governor of New Jersey Transmitting to the Legislature the Proposed Sixteenth Amendment to the Constitution of the United States Relative to the Income Tax, February 7, 1910.'' Senate Doc. No. 365, 61-2.

U.S. Senate (14 December 1910) Shall the Income-Tax Amendment Be Ratified? Senate Doc. No. 705, 61-3.

U.S. Senate (July-August 1942) Comm. on Finance, Revenue Act of 1942. Hearings [On H.R. 7378], Vol. 1, 77-2.

U.S. Senate (19 August 1942) Subcomm. of the Comm. on Finance, Withholding Tax. Hearing [On Data Relative to Withholding Provisions of the 1942 Revenue Act], 77-2.

U.S. Senate (6-7 May 1943) Comm. on Finance, Current Tax Payments Act of 1943. Hearings [On H.R. 2570], Revised, 78-1.

U.S. Senate (10 May 1943) Current Tax Payment Act of 1943. Senate Report No. 221 [To accompany H.R. 2570], Parts 1-2, 78-1.

U.S. Senate (1946) Comm. on Finance, Legislative History of the Current Tax Payment Act of 1943. Comm. Print, 79-2.

U.S. Senate (17 September 1979) Comm. on Finance, Miscellaneous Tax Bills II. Hearing, 96-1.

U.S. Senate (12 July 1982) Comm. on Finance, Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982. Senate Report No. 94-494 [To accompany H.R. 4961].

U.S. Treasury Department (1916) Annual Report of the Secretary of the Treasury on the State of Finances for the Fiscal Year Ended June 30, 1915. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Treasury Department (1917) Annual Report of the Secretary of the Treasury on the State of Finances for the Fiscal Year Ended June 30, 1916. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Treasury Department (1918) Annual Report of the Secretary of the Treasury on the State of Finances for the Fiscal Year Ended June 30, 1917. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Treasury Department (1919) Annual Report of the Secretary of the Treasury on the State of Finances for the Fiscal Year Ended June 30, 1918. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Treasury Department (1944) Annual Report of the Secretary of the Treasury on the State of Finances for the Fiscal Year Ended June 30, 1943. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

Witte, J.F. (1985) The Politics and Development of the Federal Income Tax. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

[f100]Cato Journal, Vol. 14, No. 3 (Winter 1995). Copyright ;cW Cato Institute. All rights reserved.

The author is Professor of Economics at Boise State University. She gratefully acknowledges a grant by the Earhart Foundation that facilitated this research. She wishes to thank Robert Higgs and an anonymous referee for helpful comments on an earlier draft.

[f1]Alternatively, such political transaction costs could be labeled ``constitutional-level'' transaction costs (see Twight 1988, 1992) to emphasize their influence upon the nature and extent of government authority over private decisionmaking tolerated by the public. In this broad sense, to conceptualize them as ``constitutional-level'' implies only that they influence where the line is drawn between the public sector and the private sector; it does not presuppose linkage to or embodiment in a formal constitutional document. Regarding alternative loci of a constitution, see Higgs (1988: 374-75).

[f2]Transaction-cost-manipulation theory thus is concerned with what may be called ``contrived'' political transaction costs, volitionally created by political actors for their own benefit. The residual political transaction costs that exist when all agents are attempting to minimize transaction-cost barriers to political decisionmaking will be referred to as ``natural'' transaction costs.

[f3]For example, U.S. Supreme Court redefinition of the Constitution's interstate commerce clause in ways that previously would have required constitutional amendment.

[f4]The examples in the text are intended to be suggestive rather than exhaustive. For a more complete discussion of political behaviors and policies that exemplify transaction-cost augmentation, see Twight (1994).

[f5]The complexity and appealing rationale variables require further comment. An issue's complexity may be either unavoidable (hence a ``natural'' transaction cost of understanding an issue) or itself a product of transaction-cost augmentation (hence a ``contrived'' transaction cost). Similarly, an appealing rationale may be either false (a contrived transaction cost that in turn facilitates other forms of transaction-cost augmentation) or true. In either case, the direction of impact on an officeholder's decision regarding a transaction-cost-increasing measure is as described in the text. Issue complexity, like the existence of an appealing rationale, makes it harder for citizens to perceive transaction-cost-increasing features of policy proposals. Moreover, both of these conditions allow politicians greater room to credibly claim to have made a ``mistake'' if negative public reaction to the measure's transaction-cost-increasing features does materialize.

[f6]These relationships have proved consistent with actual U.S. policymaking experience in such apparently diverse arenas as off-budget expenditure through the Federal Financing Bank, military base closures, asbestos regulation, and U.S. Social Security legislation (see Twight 1983, 1989, 1991, 1993).

[f7]The emergence and entrenchment of Social Security legislation in the United States has proved consistent with this model's description of the nexus between transaction-cost manipulation, institutional change, and ideological change (see Twight 1993).

[f8]The Supreme Court did not comment on the law's taxation of gains from business and employment, citing ``the instances in which taxation on business, privileges, or employments has assumed the guise of an excise tax [not subject to apportionment] and been sustained as such'' (158 U.S. 635). Later writers and judges interpreted Pollock to mean that the validity of such taxation was recognized and that there was ``no dispute'' about that issue (Brushaber v. Union Pacific Railroad Co., 240 U.S. 1, 17, 1915). For extended discussion of the Pollock case, see Higgs (1987: 99-103), and Arthur Ekirch Jr. (1981: 168-71).

[f9]I found only four brief references to it in thousands of pages of hearings.

[f10]On the widespread use of this rationale during World War II, see Higgs (1987).

[f11]Beardsley Ruml, of R. H. Macy & Co., was at the time chairman of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

[f12]U.S. House Hearings 1943: 184. Chairman Doughton incorporated this phrasing in a rhetorical question.

[f13]Two poll questions in May 1942 that described withholding as an idea ``to help the war effort'' found 64 percent and 72 percent of respondents supported the idea (Cantril 1951: 324).

[f14]See Higgs (1985: 2-3 ff.; 1987: 57-74).

[f15]See notes 1-7, supra, and accompanying text.

[f16]Regarding a related matter, Commissioner of Internal Revenue Roscoe L. Egger Jr. explained (U.S. House Ways & Means Comm. Hearing 1982: 19-20) that the IRS advocated a mandatory withholding tax on pensions, but that the IRS was promoting information reporting and, initially, voluntary withholding of taxes on pensions as a first step.

[f17]The Senate Finance Committee, reporting Internal Revenue Service estimates ``that 15 percent of dividend income and 11 percent of interest income is not reported by taxpayers'' while ``99 percent of wage income is reported by taxpayers,'' concluded that ``Withholding improves voluntary compliance'' (U.S. Senate Report 1982: 228).

[f18]Representative Norman E. D'Amours (D., N.H.) noted (U.S. Cong. Rec.-House, 19 August 1982: 22147) that ``One hundred and fifty Members of this body have signed a letter to the Committee on Rules asking for a separate vote. An overwhelming number of our constituents ... oppose withholding of interest and dividend taxes.''

Representative John E. Porter (R., Ill.) remarked the following year (U.S. Cong. Rec.-House, 17 May 1983: 12493) that withholding ``was just one of 96 parts of the last year's tax package, and, unfortunately, we in the House never had the opportunity to vote on the proposal separately. If it had been a free-standing proposal and not part of omnibus legislation, Congress most likely would have overwhelmingly defeated it, just as we did in 1980.''

[f19]In 1982 Representative Daniel D. Rostenkowski (D., Ill.) remarked (U.S. Cong. Rec.-House, 19 August 1982: 6555), ``The debate now in progress on interest and dividend withholding occurred 40 years ago on wage withholding. Now wage withholding is a popular system, and perceived as a relatively painless way to accurately pay taxes. I predict that in a few years, we will be able to say the same of interest and dividend withholding.''


The Cato Journal is published in the spring/summer, fall, and winter by the Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts Ave., NW, Washington, D.C. 20001-5403. The Views expressed by the authors of the articles are their own and are not attributable to the editor, editorial board, or the Cato Institute. Printed copies of the Cato Journal may be ordered by calling 1-800-767-1241. Back issues are also available on the Cato Institute Web site: http://www.cato.org. Email comments or suggestions to cato@cato.org.

19 posted on 01/18/2003 6:07:04 AM PST by vannrox (The Preamble - without it, our Bill of Rights is meaningless!)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 8 | View Replies ]


To: Uncle Bill; vannrox
BTTT!
I expected the usual Cut-n-Paste threads such as this generate and look what vannrox brought in...
59 posted on 01/23/2003 4:04:11 PM PST by philman_36
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 19 | View Replies ]

To: vannrox
The author left me hanging:

When and how much were tax rates increased after the 1943 enactment of withholding?

63 posted on 01/23/2003 4:56:38 PM PST by Old Professer
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 19 | View Replies ]

Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article


FreeRepublic, LLC, PO BOX 9771, FRESNO, CA 93794
FreeRepublic.com is powered by software copyright 2000-2008 John Robinson